Letter The following article is Open access

How healthy is the human-ocean system?

, and

Published 2 May 2014 © 2014 IOP Publishing Ltd
, , Citation Wilfried Rickels et al 2014 Environ. Res. Lett. 9 044013 DOI 10.1088/1748-9326/9/4/044013

1748-9326/9/4/044013

Abstract

Halpern et al (2012 An index to assess the health and benefits of the global ocean Nature 488 11397) propose a detailed measure of the state of the human-ocean system against ten societal goals. They devote less attention to the normative foundation of the index, which is crucial for assessing the overall health of the human-ocean system, notably when it comes to aggregation of potentially conflicting goals. Social choice theory provides several possible functional forms for assessing the compound change in various goals. The one chosen by Halpern et al, the arithmetical mean, is not only a specific but also an extreme case. It implicitly allows for unlimited substitution. A one-unit reduction in one goal can be fully offset by a one-unit increase in another with the same weighting factor. For that reason, the current index satisfies an extremely weak sustainability concept. We show that the results in Halpern et al are not robust when one adopts a strong sustainability concept. The overall health score of the ocean decreases, the ranking of the various coastal states changes substantially, and the assessment of sustainable development needs to be partially reversed.

Export citation and abstract BibTeX RIS

Content from this work may be used under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 licence. Any further distribution of this work must maintain attribution to the author(s) and the title of the work, journal citation and DOI.

1. Introduction

The ocean with its various services and resources is essential for human wealth and development—providing humanity with food, materials, essential substances, energy, and recreational opportunities. However, the free access to, and availability of, ocean resources and services has exerted major pressures on the health of the ocean, including overfishing, thoughtless pollution, or alterations to coastal zones that often cause the degradation of marine ecosystems (coral reefs, mangroves, etc), to name just a few (Visbeck et al 2014). Despite these threats, approaches to achieving more sustainable utilization of ocean resources and services are still rare, and a comprehensive understanding and assessment of the various oceanic factors influencing human wealth has not been established. Against this background, the development of an ocean-health index by Halpern et al (2012) and its subsequent annual updating is an important step towards a sustainable development strategy for the ocean.

Halpern et al (2012) define ten ocean-related societal goals to represent the ecological, social, and economic benefits of the ocean and calculate the ocean-health index at the global and local level by taking the weighted arithmetical average score of these goals. The values associated with the goals reflect not only information about the present state but also contain projections of future states derived from the assessment of the pressures on, and the resilience of, the human-ocean system. Accordingly, the values also enable us to derive information on the sustainability of human-ocean system developments. In addition, a first estimate about trends is now possible, as the scores have meanwhile been updated for the year 2013.

However, even though Halpern et al carry out a sensitivity analysis with respect to the weighting of the various goals and the discounting of future states, they leave out the sensitivity of the result to the way in which conflicting goals are aggregated. Implicitly they consider a rather extreme 'normative frame', that of unlimited substitution possibilities among the various goals. Here, we show i) that their aggregation approach should only be considered one possibility among many in assessing the human-ocean system and ii) that assuming less optimistic substitution possibilities—which seems more appropriate when assessing the sustainability of complex human-ecological systems with possible irreversible degradations—has significant implications for the overall ocean health score, the ranking of countries, and the assessment of sustainable development.

A requirement for sustainable development is that the composite endowment with environmental assets does not decrease (e.g., Pearce 1993, Arrow 2003, Dasgupta 2009). However, aggregating environmental assets requires attention to the substitution potential among them—which may be limited for ecological or technical reasons or because social preferences only allow substitution to a limited extent (e.g., Bartelmus 1989, Daly 1991, Victor 1991). Varying degrees in substitution potential are reflected by the distinction between strong and weak sustainability. The concept of strong sustainability requires keeping all assets above critical levels to maintain sustainable development because it does not allow for substitution between them. The concept of weak sustainability, by contrast, allows for unlimited substitution and requires that the aggregate of the various assets (valued with their respective shadow prices) does not decline (e.g., Pearce et al 1989, Daly and Cobb 1989, Hartwick 1990, Hamilton 1994). Obviously, there exists a broad spectrum between these two extremes, and the appropriate level of substitution potential can be expected to differ dependent on the characteristics of the underlying assets to be assessed (e.g., Bateman et al 2011). However, facing complex ecological-human interactions like the human-ocean system, limited substitution possibilities satisfying a rather strong sustainability concept seem to be better suited to accounting adequately for the influence of the various stocks on wealth (e.g., Dasgupta and Heal 1979, Pearce et al 1989, Ekins et al 2003, Ayres 2007, Visbeck et al 2014).

We employ results from social choice theory to show that, based on the underlying assumptions in Halpern et al (2012), a meaningful aggregation of the individual goal scores can be obtained by applying a generalized mean. Accordingly, there is a full family of specific functional forms for the ocean-health index depending on the specification of a parameter that characterizes the substitution possibilities. Following the literature on natural resource and ecosystem assessment, we assume limited substitution possibilities for the various goals reflecting the state of the human-ocean system. Decreasing the substitution parameter lowers the overall index from 65 to 52 in 2012 and 2013 because it reduces the potential for offsetting poorer performances in certain goals by better performances in other goals. The implications of a decreased substitution parameter become more striking when we turn to the assessment of individual countries. Countries with an unbalanced performance across the goals significantly deteriorate in the ranking compared to countries with a balanced performance. For example, Russia and Greenland fall in the ranking for 2013 by about 107 and 118 places (out of 220) respectively, while Indonesia and Peru improve by about 78 and 88 places respectively.

This effect also becomes significant in assessing the sustainability of current development by comparing the scores between 2012 and 2013. For 29 out of 220 countries, the ocean-health index increases if we assume unlimited substitution possibilities but decreases if we assume limited substitution possibilities. By contrast, there are 21 countries whose score deteriorates under a concept of weak sustainability (unlimited substitution possibilities) but improves under a concept of strong sustainability. Hence we conclude that appropriate ocean management and governance requires thoughtful attention to the method used for data aggregation and the value of the parameter quantifying substitution possibilities among the various goals if we are to obtain a meaningful and appropriate assessment of the state of the human-ocean system.

2. Methods

The ten ocean-related societal goals of the ocean health index are 1) 'Artisanal Fishing Opportunities', 2) 'Biodiversity' ('Species' and 'Habitats'), 3) 'Coastal Protection', 4) 'Carbon Storage', 5) 'Clean Waters', 6) 'Food Provision' ('Wild Caught Fisheries' and 'Mariculture'), 7) 'Coastal Livelihoods&Economics' ('Livelihoods' and 'Economics'), 8) 'Natural Products', 9) 'Sense of Place' ('Iconic Species' and 'Lasting Special Places'), and 10) 'Tourism&Recreation' (Halpern et al 2012). Certain goals are aggregates of subgoals indicated by the terms in the parenthesis above. The goals and subgoals reflect the present and future state, the latter being derived from the assessment of the pressures on, and the resilience of, the specific goal. The ocean-health index is obtained by aggregating the various goals and is calculated at global and local level. Its first release in 2012 provided a ranking of 171 coastal states and regions based on the condition of their marine ecosystems in their EEZs. The index is updated annually, and at present information on ocean health for the year 2013 is already available on the ocean-health index website 4 . The updated ocean-health index for 2012 and 2013 ranks a total of 220 countries/islands compared to 171 countries/regions in Halpern et al. This is due to the fact that previously aggregated regions (like, say, the USA Pacific Uninhabited Territories) have now been evaluated and assessed separately.

In compiling an index, $I$, like the ocean-health index, a major challenge is the aggregation of different goals reflecting issues as different as oceanic carbon uptake and the number of jobs in the fishery sector. Generally, achieving a meaningful aggregation of such ratio-scale but non-comparable goals would require applying a (weighted) geometric mean (e.g., Ebert and Welsch, 2004). However, such an index would (a) only allow for an ordinal and not a cardinal comparison of the coastal zones and (b) preclude investigation of different levels for the substitution possibilities.

Consequently, Halpern et al assume the existence of goal-specific scaling factors to obtain fully comparable ratio-scale indicators or goals. The scaling factors are obtained by the potential goal-specific best value, thus producing individual goals ranging between 0 and 1 that are then rescaled in terms of the ratio-scale property to be in the range between 0 and 100. According to social choice theory, meaningful aggregation for $N$ ratio-scaled indicators or goals ${{I}_{i}}$ is obtained by applying generalized means (Blackorby and Donaldson, 1982):

Equation (1)

with weights ${{\alpha }_{i}}>0$ and $0 \leqslant \sigma \leqslant \infty .$ The parameter $\sigma $ quantifies the elasticity of substitution between the different indicators for generating ocean health (Solow 1956, Arrow et al 1961, Armington 1969). Thus the ratio-scale fully comparable goals allow for a full class of specific functional forms for the index dependent on $\sigma $, which we denote by $I(\sigma )$ because we do not consider any variation in the weights or the individual indicators. Halpern et al have chosen the extreme case of unlimited substitution, $\sigma \to \infty $, which results in the arithmetical weighted mean

Equation (2)

For this specification of $\sigma $, the distribution of scores over the different indicators only has any bearing on the value of the ocean-health index to the extent that the constant weighing factors may differ.

Considering limited substitution possibilities instead, and hence subscribing to a concept of relatively strong sustainability, requires choosing a value for $\sigma $ below 1 (e.g., Gerlagh and van der Zwaan 2002, Heal 2009, Bateman et al 2011, Traeger 2013). More specifically, Sterner and Persson (2008) suggest using $\sigma =0.5$ in their study of the human-climate system. Instead of choosing a specific value for $\sigma $, we assume $\sigma $ to be uniformly distributed between 0 and 1 and perform a Monte Carlo simulation ($n=10\;000$) to recalculate the ocean-health index for 2012 and 2013 based on the equally-weighted individual goal scores obtained from the ocean-health website. The simulation results are not only used to derive the average score but also to calculate a ranking for each simulation and obtain average ranking information. Coastal states with one or more zero scores in an individual goal obtain an index value of zero for $\sigma \leqslant 1$ (22 and 21 countries in 2012 and 2013 respectively). Accordingly, all these countries were ranked last. To obtain further ranking information for these countries, we performed stepwise exclusion of those goals with a zero score. Accordingly, complete rankings for 220 countries have now been obtained. To further test the sensitivity of the results to the strong sustainability assumption, we repeated the entire calculation with $\sigma $ assumed to be exponentially distributed with mean 0.5 so that substitution elasticities above 1 are also considered in the Monte Carlo simulation. The comparison of changes in ocean-health scores between 2012 and 2013 for the different specifications makes for further insights about the sensitivity of sustainable development to the substitution possibilities.

3. Results

Under a concept of weak sustainability (unlimited substitution possibilities, $\sigma \to \infty $) as assumed by Halpern et al, the index value for both 2012 and 2013 is 65 (with the best possible value being 100). If instead of this we apply a concept of strong sustainability with $\sigma $ uniformly distributed between 0 and 1, the index values decrease to 52.14 (±8.26) and 51.99 (±8.17) in 2013 and 2012 respectively. The figures in parentheses show the standard deviation. The reduction in the index value is a necessary result of reducing the substitution possibilities because low substitution possibilities imply an unambiguously lower absolute score than with unlimited substitution possibilities, except for the special case of an equal (weighted) score in each goal. The concept of strong sustainability, corresponding to low substitution possibilities, imposes greater restrictions on the potential to compensate for poor performance in certain goals and therefore gives more weight to low-performing goals. Accordingly, assuming $\sigma $ to be distributed exponentially with mean 0.5 and hence allowing for substitution elasticities above 1 results in a less extreme reduction of ocean-health scores, i.e. 57.92 (±8.07) and 57.70 (±7.98) for 2013 and 2012 respectively.

The implications of differences in substitution possibilities become especially important when comparing the performance of various countries or when assessing development over time. Figure 1 shows the rankings of the 220 countries for $\sigma \to \infty $ and $\sigma \tilde{\ }U(0,1)$ in 2013, where the error bars indicate the standard deviation obtained from the sensitivity analysis. Without any effect from varying the substitution parameter, data points for all countries would be on the 45° line. The figure reveals, however, that the distribution of scores across goals significantly changes the ranking. Above the 45° line are those countries with a rather unbalanced performance and therefore with lower rankings under limited substitution possibilities than under perfect substitution possibilities, and vice versa for countries below the 45° line. Figures A1 and A2 in the appendix show the results for the first 50 countries in 2013 in more detail (A1) and the ranking comparison for 2012 (A2). Table A1 in the appendix provides index and ranking information for 2013 for all countries and islands and the change in the index between 2012 and 2013 resulting from the different specification for the substitution possibilities 5 .

Figure 1.

Figure 1. Comparison of ocean-health rankings in 2013 for 220 countries with unlimited substitution possibilities (weak sustainability) and with limited substitution possibilities (strong sustainability). The data point is in the middle of the respective country's name; error bars indicate $\pm 1$ standard deviation.

Standard image High-resolution image
Figure A1.

Figure A1. Detailed comparison of ocean-health rankings in 2013 for the first 50 countries ranked according to unlimited substitution possibilites.

Standard image High-resolution image
Figure A2.

Figure A2. Comparison of ocean-health rankings in 2012 for 220 countries with unlimited substitution possibilities (weak sustainability) and with limited substitution possibilities (strong sustainability). The data point is in the middle of the respective country's name (with +/− standard deviation).

Standard image High-resolution image

Table A1.  Ocean-health index, ranking, and change for the various specifications of substitution elasticity.

      Ocean-Health Index 2013 Ocean Health Ranking 2013 Change in OH Index 2013–2012
      σ →  σ ∼ U(0,1) σ ∼ exp(0.5) SD U(0,1) SD exp(0.5) σ → a σ ∼ U(0,1) σ ∼ exp(0.5) SD U(0,1) SD exp(0.5) σ →  σ ∼ U(0,1) σ ∼ exp(0.5)
Heard+McDonald Is 93.75 92.40 93.03 1.95 1.56 1 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 −0.75 −1.13 −0.97
Saba 90.00 86.44 88.11 4.20 3.47 2 2.00 2.00 0.00 0.00 −1.44 −2.41 −2.00
Howland+Baker Is 87.40 82.94 85.04 4.96 4.13 3 3.00 3.00 0.00 0.00 1.60 1.40 1.48
Kerguelen Is 86.20 81.35 83.62 4.91 4.18 4 4.00 4.00 0.00 0.00 −1.00 −2.12 −1.62
Sint-Eustatius 84.56 65.74 74.92 15.67 14.24 5 11.64 8.55 8.38 6.76 −1.44 −1.00 −1.31
Phoenix Group 84.43 66.31 75.11 14.56 13.38 6 10.21 8.41 4.71 3.84 0.14 −2.47 −1.19
Bonaire 83.89 75.26 79.38 9.19 7.75 7 5.03 5.39 0.18 0.73 −1.11 −1.01 −1.14
Prince Edward Iss 83.20 63.49 72.93 13.57 13.16 8 12.71 10.33 3.81 3.58 0.00 0.03 0.00
Northern Saint-Martin 81.50 67.13 74.02 12.34 11.06 9 8.79 9.11 1.20 0.89 −0.5 −0.28 −0.45
Curacao 80.89 70.93 75.69 10.01 8.57 10 6.72 8.31 0.87 1.56 −2.00 −1.55 −1.87
S. Georgia+S. Sandwich Is 80.00 50.81 64.89 16.12 17.29 11 41.94 24.71 18.53 19.91 8.60 2.76 6.08
Seychelles 77.30 59.88 68.14 11.83 11.51 12 16.44 14.50 3.87 3.29 −0.70 −1.89 −1.36
Tuvalu 77.33 60.68 68.62 12.09 11.47 13 14.80 13.23 4.28 3.44 2.11 −0.02 1.05
Wallis and Futuna 75.75 59.77 67.32 10.90 10.58 14 15.81 15.14 1.46 1.19 2.63 1.05 1.86
Aruba 75.60 50.00 62.40 16.00 16.21 15 45.37 30.15 18.25 18.94 −0.60 1.63 0.50
Vanuatu 75.50 57.58 66.11 12.20 11.87 16 21.32 18.51 6.13 5.12 1.30 0.84 1.07
British Indian Ocean Territory 75.25 62.24 68.45 11.07 9.94 17 11.86 13.37 1.36 1.60 1.00 1.87 1.48
Croatia 74.38 52.79 63.30 15.18 14.66 18 35.76 26.56 14.81 13.54 0.00 −0.05 −0.05
Norway 74.11 55.83 64.66 13.95 13.04 19 26.34 22.23 11.1 8.92 3.89 3.04 3.47
Macquarie Is 74.25 41.43 56.97 14.57 17.47 20 79.11 51.80 13.52 26.04 −0.75 3.83 1.74
Netherlands 73.70 51.80 62.25 13.33 13.61 21 39.81 30.91 9.93 10.58 1.00 1.01 1.02
Reunion 73.75 45.42 59.06 15.73 16.81 22 63.15 42.37 17.01 22.04 0.13 −1.79 −0.79
Ile Europa 73.80 0.00 33.26 0.00 30.59 23 200.16 140.50 0.37 69.09 0.80 0.00 0.14
Amsterdam+Saint Paul Is 73.60 15.10 43.18 13.13 26.11 24 180.49 113.98 8.12 60.69 0.00 −0.06 0.04
New Zealand 73.60 55.01 63.98 14.04 13.17 25 29.13 24.81 11.25 9.13 0.30 1.85 1.05
Crozet Is 73.50 59.36 66.00 9.65 9.34 26 16.34 18.92 2.17 2.85 −0.50 −1.58 −1.10
Antigua+Barbuda 73.20 17.05 45.42 16.62 27.10 27 172.72 100.68 20.21 63.65 −2.30 −0.48 −1.33
Marshall Is 73.30 57.74 65.17 11.19 10.66 28 21.11 22.07 2.82 2.09 2.50 0.13 1.27
Nauru 72.75 56.05 63.94 10.78 10.70 29 25.65 25.60 1.89 1.53 1.38 −1.00 0.13
Malta 72.60 40.76 56.15 16.46 18.26 30 80.37 54.76 19.22 26.85 −0.10 −0.09 −0.05
France 72.60 65.12 68.57 5.76 5.31 31 10.70 17.00 3.25 6.39 0.30 0.14 0.18
Estonia 72.50 37.53 54.53 17.62 19.83 31 93.77 63.01 23.57 32.30 0.60 −1.25 −0.22
Jarvis Is 72.50 44.55 57.78 13.63 15.49 33 66.21 49.01 9.27 16.79 2.25 0.77 1.54
Portugal 72.38 54.65 63.10 12.32 11.89 34 30.31 28.59 6.17 4.78 0.25 1.29 0.78
Trinidad+Tobago 72.00 43.16 57.38 17.57 18.07 35 71.47 48.88 22.51 25.73 −0.40 1.05 0.33
Cape Verde 71.86 55.32 62.94 9.38 9.79 36 28.29 29.18 3.86 3.38 −1.29 −0.27 −0.84
Belgium 71.40 48.01 58.90 11.64 13.01 37 54.97 46.87 3.22 8.02 0.70 1.26 1.03
Madeira 71.14 58.23 64.30 9.58 8.98 38 19.85 25.70 2.86 6.09 0.00 1.15 0.55
Norfolk Is 70.86 39.96 55.14 16.67 18.18 39 83.82 61.91 20.2 24.4 −1.29 −0.43 −0.77
Greece 70.75 53.09 61.44 11.05 11.11 40 36.10 35.01 2.09 2.81 0.13 1.64 0.92
Finland 70.33 51.46 60.22 10.64 11.16 41 43.41 43.37 1.86 1.56 0.33 0.40 0.39
Monaco 70.43 53.25 61.32 11.17 11.03 42 35.42 36.03 2.34 2.87 2.00 1.28 1.64
Australia 70.20 47.91 58.60 14.35 14.31 43 54.98 47.58 9.13 9.58 −1.60 0.26 −0.66
Mauritius 70.50 49.09 59.16 12.09 12.72 44 52.24 47.31 2.51 4.82 1.10 5.61 3.40
Chile+Easter Is 70.25 50.74 59.89 11.26 11.72 45 46.53 44.85 1.45 2.38 1.25 0.75 0.99
Azores 70.00 52.03 60.54 11.88 11.67 46 40.14 40.15 3.46 4.16 −0.29 −0.14 −0.24
Maldives 70.00 55.07 62.16 10.88 10.31 47 28.94 33.07 2.77 5.29 −0.30 −0.03 −0.18
Bermuda 69.67 26.66 48.07 17.62 22.62 48 140.37 94.87 25.12 43.07 −0.56 −0.35 −0.37
French Polynesia 69.50 52.80 60.59 9.83 10.13 49 38.73 43.04 3.63 4.91 1.10 0.29 0.70
Tokelau 69.44 52.06 60.07 9.97 10.35 50 42.09 46.90 4.39 5.35 0.33 −0.43 −0.11
Line Group 69.29 0.00 32.73 0.00 29.23 51 203.15 148.83 1.93 58.36 0.00 0.00 −0.31
Palau 69.20 54.45 61.36 9.86 9.62 52 31.86 38.86 2.97 7.42 0.30 −1.02 −0.44
Denmark 69.20 45.04 56.33 12.26 13.58 53 64.13 60.00 3.11 4.23 1.00 1.97 1.55
Montserrat 68.89 15.47 42.28 15.05 25.42 54 183.32 122.33 16.48 54.55 −1.44 −0.32 −0.80
Gibraltar 69.14 49.52 59.02 13.51 13.13 55 48.59 47.83 7.33 5.83 −1.86 −1.83 −1.88
Morocco 68.75 56.00 61.92 8.94 8.54 56 26.82 37.97 5.83 11.65 0.88 0.64 0.73
Jan Mayen 68.88 53.58 60.70 9.84 9.74 57 35.35 43.93 2.91 7.98 1.38 1.21 1.26
Bassas da India 68.50 0.00 29.15 0.00 27.58 58 200.84 167.88 0.37 46.71 0.75 0.00 0.11
Germany 68.30 37.75 52.03 13.65 16.23 59 94.49 79.38 5.85 13.85 0.70 1.34 1.06
Western Sahara 68.29 54.45 60.86 8.44 8.53 60 32.80 44.67 8.45 12.26 2.14 3.65 2.95
Canada 68.30 49.85 58.47 11.55 11.57 61 50.29 54.30 2.19 3.62 −0.90 0.46 −0.26
Fiji 68.00 51.82 59.57 12.18 11.42 62 41.10 48.62 4.93 7.14 0.10 −1.20 −0.58
Palmyra Atoll 67.80 37.07 51.93 14.64 16.99 63 95.99 78.13 10.77 16.91 1.80 0.47 1.18
Johnston Atoll 67.60 37.00 51.80 14.58 16.92 64 97.17 79.87 10.42 16.35 1.80 0.48 1.18
Juan de Nova Is 67.86 0.00 30.93 0.00 27.87 65 210.83 165.35 3.11 50.24 0.43 0.00 0.01
Glorioso Iss 67.71 0.00 30.87 0.00 27.82 66 211.71 166.82 2.94 49.57 0.43 0.00 0.01
Brunei 67.20 43.78 54.80 13.04 13.82 67 70.06 67.90 5.54 4.82 −1.60 −1.16 −1.31
Sint-Maarten 67.22 24.96 45.44 16.01 21.36 68 149.22 113.07 17.68 34.18 0.22 2.56 1.44
Cocos Iss 67.11 25.90 46.33 16.85 21.62 69 144.35 106.52 21.5 36.12 −1.00 −0.28 −0.48
Pitcairn 67.13 42.21 53.81 12.65 13.99 70 76.28 72.55 4.48 4.65 1.88 0.28 1.01
Egypt 67.30 44.96 55.53 12.41 13.19 71 64.40 63.84 2.78 2.66 2.40 1.47 1.99
New Caledonia 67.20 58.07 62.39 8.45 7.38 72 21.13 38.51 6.80 17.14 0.90 0.65 0.73
Thailand 67.00 59.46 62.97 6.60 5.84 73 19.17 38.76 8.08 19.03 1.70 1.56 1.60
Canary Iss 67.00 59.59 62.99 5.62 5.20 74 20.65 40.48 9.37 19.42 0.11 0.69 0.37
United States 66.90 50.10 58.10 12.04 11.48 75 48.88 56.12 4.34 6.90 0.30 0.84 0.54
Cuba 66.80 29.21 47.24 15.70 19.60 76 130.83 105.03 16.01 25.59 0.00 −0.09 0.03
Anguilla 66.56 19.64 43.01 15.86 23.22 77 166.54 123.65 16.07 38.93 −0.33 4.37 1.99
Saint Kitts+Nevis 66.44 22.65 44.22 16.10 22.10 78 156.07 119.26 16.13 33.86 2.00 3.53 2.81
Christmas Is 66.44 19.38 42.73 15.61 23.13 79 168.28 126.54 14.89 37.76 −1.11 −0.26 −0.54
Oman 66.56 50.49 57.77 8.43 9.08 80 47.88 58.41 9.37 12.17 −1.56 0.03 −0.76
Russia 66.50 13.97 39.04 12.97 23.65 80 187.11 145.92 7.46 37.43 −0.90 −0.16 −0.41
Guatemala 66.40 34.27 49.71 15.28 17.70 82 109.04 92.23 12.70 17.35 −1.90 −15.21 −8.76
Brazil + Trindade 66.30 40.45 52.62 13.09 14.56 83 83.77 79.08 4.84 5.60 0.20 −1.48 −0.63
Sweden 66.20 37.29 51.34 15.85 17.07 84 94.89 82.83 14.83 15.11 −1.1 0.90 −0.10
Greenland 66.33 0.00 32.62 0.00 28.55 85 202.92 153.50 0.75 49.01 0.89 0.00 0.31
Spain 66.20 54.32 59.86 8.86 8.28 86 34.22 50.73 9.29 16.22 −0.50 0.28 −0.13
Japan 66.20 26.42 45.39 15.15 20.02 87 142.99 117.86 12.53 23.90 0.40 −0.03 0.26
Latvia 66.00 49.16 56.91 9.38 9.87 88 52.48 62.15 6.93 10.79 −0.20 −1.24 −0.78
Cayman Iss 66.00 0.00 31.23 0.00 27.56 89 217.36 169.19 2.18 47.64 −0.90 0.00 −1.10
Djibouti 65.89 34.10 49.11 14.25 16.97 90 110.3 98.82 7.11 11.18 0.11 0.02 0.13
British Virgin Iss 65.78 32.08 48.68 16.53 18.97 91 118.64 97.42 19.02 22.97 1.22 2.23 1.84
Ireland 65.70 47.80 56.12 10.35 10.72 92 56.69 65.71 4.77 9.79 0.00 −0.58 −0.30
Wake Is 65.63 26.79 45.89 16.03 20.39 93 140.87 114.04 17.47 26.21 1.13 −0.07 0.54
Guadeloupe+ Martinique 65.60 15.17 40.05 14.29 23.76 94 180.08 139.79 10.68 35.95 0.50 0.87 1.22
Turks+Caicos Iss 65.60 36.53 50.35 14.40 16.25 95 99.63 92.00 7.68 8.90 −0.60 1.15 0.34
Dominican Republic 65.60 31.11 48.22 17.01 19.50 96 122.26 100.02 20.19 24.12 −0.20 1.96 0.96
Slovenia 65.00 42.55 52.89 11.25 12.48 97 75.79 82.86 4.19 8.14 2.00 1.25 1.70
Ukraine 65.10 41.12 52.57 13.91 14.52 98 80.63 81.01 9.07 8.49 −1.70 −2.13 −1.95
Suriname 64.90 13.72 38.26 12.72 23.14 99 188.81 152.00 6.36 33.08 −5.90 −1.08 −3.81
United Arab Emirates 64.40 41.04 51.77 11.19 12.71 100 83.00 91.08 4.38 8.77 0.60 −0.46 0.08
Niue 64.44 43.88 53.36 10.90 11.75 101 69.70 81.66 5.26 12.68 −0.33 −1.86 −1.17
French Guiana 64.50 30.12 46.41 14.76 18.04 102 126.53 115.35 10.41 12.3 −1.40 2.32 0.25
Malaysia 64.40 43.79 53.45 11.24 12.02 103 69.53 79.67 3.42 11.37 0.20 0.78 0.51
Gambia 64.30 49.70 56.52 9.47 9.35 104 50.66 67.29 6.96 17.34 −2.80 −4.29 −3.68
United Kingdom 64.10 44.08 53.43 11.95 12.23 105 67.38 80.70 3.02 13.74 0.80 0.42 0.59
Jersey 64.00 53.29 58.13 6.08 6.30 106 39.16 62.78 16.39 25.92 −1.13 −0.63 −0.86
Saint Helena 64.13 43.59 53.26 12.21 12.54 106 70.56 81.06 3.42 11.97 −1.38 −0.88 −1.19
Romania 64.00 42.55 52.54 11.32 12.27 108 75.74 86.77 3.67 11.73 −2.00 0.92 −0.47
Israel 63.80 29.15 45.24 13.23 17.27 109 131.71 123.18 3.73 8.11 −0.7 −0.14 −0.34
Italy 63.20 41.99 51.89 11.15 12.12 110 78.63 90.92 4.61 12.48 0.00 1.19 0.60
Ecuador + Galapagos 63.00 39.45 50.63 13.05 13.89 111 89.13 97.08 4.48 8.64 1.40 1.28 1.28
Northern Mariana Iss and Guam 63.00 33.69 47.82 14.81 16.59 112 113.52 110.09 10.79 8.90 2.56 0.62 1.63
Bangladesh 62.90 11.50 35.13 10.39 21.97 112 195.86 170.44 1.78 25.74 0.10 −6.97 −3.51
Belize 62.80 35.32 48.43 14.37 15.76 114 105.06 107.07 6.94 6.37 0.50 0.11 0.30
South Korea 62.88 46.80 54.12 8.65 9.22 115 60.46 82.09 10.07 21.67 1.25 0.75 1.02
Tunisia 62.63 43.46 52.16 9.27 10.43 116 73.82 92.38 11.27 19.10 2.13 0.47 1.31
Lithuania 62.67 38.57 49.67 11.11 12.89 117 92.97 103.63 6.03 10.95 0.33 0.60 0.51
Qatar 62.70 33.31 46.97 13.21 15.60 117 113.46 115.58 2.37 2.81 0.20 −5.54 −2.70
Uruguay 62.25 13.32 37.36 12.73 22.64 119 193.09 159.3 7.88 29.89 −1.00 −0.26 −0.59
Puerto Rico+Virgin Is 61.89 30.49 45.37 13.91 16.69 120 125.35 123.55 7.07 5.30 −0.22 0.07 0.01
Argentina 61.75 49.87 55.26 6.80 7.03 121 50.04 79.33 15.27 29.85 0.25 1.81 1.08
Colombia 61.70 36.61 48.60 13.31 14.52 122 100.09 108.00 3.33 8.43 0.00 1.56 0.87
Mexico 61.70 43.48 52.11 11.58 11.57 123 71.65 91.52 4.88 19.02 1.50 6.12 3.80
Benin 61.60 29.68 44.77 14.23 16.98 124 128.64 126.79 6.97 5.36 −0.20 −1.64 −0.86
Comoro Iss 61.30 39.04 49.29 11.08 12.34 125 91.10 106.58 7.09 15.04 2.20 1.38 1.75
American Samoa 61.56 41.25 50.65 10.84 11.66 126 82.87 100.30 6.67 17.05 1.56 0.47 0.99
Faeroe Is 61.33 0.00 29.97 0.00 26.26 127 206.09 174.11 0.85 31.97 1.56 0.00 0.66
Bahamas 61.20 37.51 48.40 11.24 12.83 128 98.23 111.65 5.93 12.97 0.30 −0.05 0.05
Equatorial Guinea 61.00 29.91 44.29 11.88 15.47 129 127.91 130.62 5.41 4.75 0.50 1.05 0.83
Kiribati 60.90 26.66 43.25 14.99 18.24 130 141.78 134.33 10.25 9.87 0.00 −0.21 −0.05
Sao Tome+Principe 60.75 31.92 45.34 12.72 15.19 131 119.41 125.58 1.40 5.75 −0.38 1.35 0.60
Solomon Iss 60.90 32.86 46.23 13.92 15.69 132 115.17 120.62 5.62 6.7 −0.90 −10.42 −5.64
Syria 60.75 39.09 49.15 10.92 12.12 133 90.99 108.08 7.08 16.54 0.00 0.02 0.03
South Africa 60.60 25.55 42.20 14.12 17.95 134 147.56 140.75 5.62 7.23 0.80 −1.61 −0.32
Costa Rica 60.70 46.80 53.30 9.56 9.21 135 60.44 88.77 8.55 26.92 0.80 0.10 0.40
Ile Tromelin 60.60 0.00 26.67 0.00 24.65 136 203.92 188.75 0.64 23.17 0.80 0.00 0.19
Papua New Guinea 60.40 30.29 44.46 12.8 15.71 137 127.06 130.43 1.84 3.64 −0.40 −1.56 −0.96
Saint Pierre+Miquelon 60.56 0.00 29.65 0.00 25.97 138 206.05 176.64 1.12 29.51 0.11 0.00 −0.08
Mayotte 60.30 25.35 41.67 12.86 17.24 139 148.68 144.40 1.71 4.18 0.60 1.53 1.09
Albania 60.00 27.10 42.46 12.97 16.61 140 141.69 140.78 1.30 2.18 0.38 1.73 1.14
Lebanon 59.75 24.89 40.74 11.60 16.45 141 149.74 150.38 4.76 4.86 0.38 −0.04 0.16
Falkland Is 59.57 48.55 53.42 5.46 6.01 142 56.23 92.41 22.23 37.16 −1.14 −0.65 −0.94
Taiwan 59.40 32.95 45.24 12.69 14.44 143 114.74 127.39 2.29 11.38 0.20 1.08 0.61
Jamaica 59.10 14.07 36.18 12.9 21.21 144 185.05 166.85 4.85 16.15 0.40 −0.09 0.20
Guernsey 59.13 0.00 28.50 0.00 25.17 145 205.32 183.59 1.69 23.33 −1.00 0.00 −0.62
Bouvet Is 59.00 0.00 25.02 0.00 23.34 146 210.36 199.26 0.69 17.6 −0.40 0.00 −0.49
Togo 58.60 26.61 41.58 13.28 16.46 147 144.40 147.12 2.67 4.24 −0.7 −0.48 −0.58
Namibia 58.88 23.47 40.16 13.03 17.52 148 155.48 153.21 2.81 3.06 0.38 −3.74 −1.75
Poland 58.60 23.04 40.03 13.77 18.00 149 156.11 152.96 4.74 4.68 0.20 −0.06 0.14
Indonesia 58.40 43.96 50.78 9.34 9.26 150 71.55 103.07 12.34 30.31 1.20 1.42 1.29
Georgia 58.75 37.10 46.77 9.17 11.04 150 99.21 122.87 14.03 23.54 0.50 −3.56 −1.81
Bahrain 58.30 39.27 48.00 9.41 10.50 152 90.71 117.08 14.21 26.15 1.70 0.70 1.22
Saint Lucia 58.50 18.51 38.17 14.14 19.90 152 168.93 158.44 7.21 10.33 −1.50 −0.44 −0.90
Cook Is 58.20 13.80 35.35 12.55 20.70 154 186.31 172.73 2.89 11.78 −0.20 −0.19 −0.18
Mauritania 58.00 34.56 45.13 9.56 11.82 155 110.39 131.39 12.61 21.38 0.13 0.55 0.32
Iceland 58.00 38.27 47.56 11.32 11.82 156 95.35 118.97 6.97 22.12 −1.67 −0.78 −1.23
Sri Lanka 57.80 27.21 41.84 13.72 16.38 157 140.80 145.65 4.39 7.39 −1.70 −0.62 −1.10
India 57.80 38.46 47.84 12.82 12.65 158 93.10 116.16 5.41 21.45 −0.30 −0.16 −0.24
Bulgaria 57.75 19.29 37.75 13.06 18.71 159 167.80 164.11 4.50 4.71 −4.25 −0.74 −2.28
Mozambique 57.80 13.56 35.01 12.3 20.56 160 188.38 175.48 2.31 11.12 −0.80 −0.10 −0.32
China 57.60 14.69 36.30 13.55 20.98 161 180.95 167.01 6.97 12.53 0.10 −0.08 0.11
Iraq 57.22 30.09 42.63 11.04 13.82 162 127.53 143.68 9.69 16.41 1.89 0.19 1.01
Kuwait 57.10 26.84 40.77 12.14 15.28 163 142.48 154.25 3.34 10.62 −1.00 −0.22 −0.54
Peru 57.00 42.76 49.48 10.07 9.62 164 75.92 110.96 12.74 33.36 0.6 1.86 1.22
Saudi Arabia 56.80 34.70 44.50 8.68 10.90 165 110.47 137.00 18.32 27.56 0.6 −0.30 0.12
Philippines 56.40 36.77 45.98 10.46 11.31 166 100.96 128.47 8.97 26.19 −0.6 −0.63 −0.62
Vietnam 56.20 31.88 43.19 10.90 12.90 167 120.86 141.90 9.77 20.80 1.20 3.56 2.41
Cyprus 55.88 29.06 41.61 11.82 14.15 167 134.23 151.25 5.44 15.63 −3.25 −0.86 −1.95
Andaman+Nicobar 56.11 13.36 34.52 12.31 20.26 169 193.02 180.00 4.69 11.48 −0.56 −0.14 −0.25
Tonga 56.00 35.02 44.38 8.81 10.65 170 108.87 138.20 17.34 29.26 1.60 −0.54 0.34
Micronesia 55.90 17.22 35.82 12.82 18.68 171 174.40 173.16 3.01 3.49 0.10 −0.29 −0.12
Turkey 55.88 11.23 31.86 10.13 19.40 172 198.14 191.40 0.93 7.44 1.25 −0.02 0.52
Cameroon 55.30 18.32 35.78 11.83 17.57 173 171.05 174.27 1.81 3.53 0.50 2.77 1.76
Tanzania 55.00 16.06 34.51 11.77 18.24 174 178.81 179.73 2.09 2.29 0.60 −0.18 0.21
Kenya 54.70 20.54 36.55 11.78 16.53 175 164.10 172.31 1.59 7.50 −0.30 −1.88 −1.04
Montenegro 54.50 35.22 43.98 9.16 10.40 176 107.61 141.27 15.75 32.01 0.50 1.01 0.77
Panama 54.30 30.04 41.34 11.71 13.29 177 128.36 153.52 8.17 22.96 −1.20 −3.68 −2.44
Grenada 54.20 34.37 43.69 11.26 11.81 178 109.40 140.09 8.63 28.38 −0.10 0.96 0.43
Gabon 54.10 27.40 40.51 13.68 15.30 179 139.58 156.63 4.57 16.02 2.30 2.62 2.58
East Timor 54.10 34.93 43.86 9.88 10.84 180 108.77 141.71 11.86 31.00 0.20 0.80 0.53
Madagascar 54.10 32.67 42.85 11.47 12.43 181 117.46 145.10 7.68 25.61 −0.10 −1.17 −0.63
Honduras 54.20 15.79 34.13 11.62 18.08 182 180.29 182.19 2.61 2.75 0.80 0.04 0.46
Jordan 53.90 21.04 36.63 12.14 16.34 183 162.36 172.22 1.12 9.27 −1.00 −0.23 −0.52
Libya 53.75 26.50 39.06 11.06 13.84 184 144.24 163.42 7.38 18.28 2.13 −0.73 0.68
Singapore 53.70 0.00 25.88 0.00 22.62 185 211.03 200.85 2.04 9.69 −1.60 0.00 −1.00
Barbados 53.60 12.47 31.88 10.96 18.63 186 191.49 191.14 2.59 2.12 −0.50 −0.03 −0.12
Guyana 53.40 17.36 35.02 12.89 17.97 187 173.06 177.96 2.89 6.06 0.50 3.99 2.33
Dominica 53.40 11.90 31.41 10.44 18.56 188 193.85 193.75 2.55 2.68 0.00 −0.09 −0.02
Oecussi Ambeno 53.13 43.83 47.99 5.51 5.57 189 75.92 125.28 26.67 49.11 −0.25 0.17 −0.03
El Salvador 53.10 27.10 39.13 11.06 13.47 190 141.03 163.41 7.88 21.1 1.60 1.27 1.36
Rep Congo 52.88 18.18 34.72 11.88 16.86 191 172.65 180.54 2.01 7.32 1.25 −1.99 −0.31
Cambodia 52.60 15.13 33.18 11.16 17.68 192 182.58 186.22 4.06 4.63 −1.20 −2.97 −2.04
Eritrea 52.60 17.40 33.58 10.79 16.30 193 174.57 185.58 6.91 10.73 −7.20 −14.43 −11.35
Algeria 52.63 25.64 37.57 9.46 12.78 194 146.76 170.77 12.20 22.92 2.63 0.47 1.43
Bosnia+Herzegovina 52.13 14.69 32.29 10.81 17.26 195 184.81 191.12 3.98 6.34 −0.38 −0.38 −0.44
North Korea 52.00 0.00 24.30 0.00 21.47 196 213.59 207.17 1.49 6.13 −0.22 0.00 −0.32
Ascension 51.43 0.00 23.82 0.00 21.34 197 209.20 206.76 1.47 4.15 −1.14 0.00 −0.70
Saint Vincent+ Grenadines 51.00 18.23 33.69 11.55 15.97 198 171.79 185.57 3.87 12.38 1.33 3.15 2.42
Samoa 50.90 20.80 34.83 11.60 15.02 199 163.03 181.18 4.05 16.18 0.00 −1.73 −0.75
Tristan da Cunha 50.71 0.00 23.27 0.00 20.90 200 211.10 209.08 1.09 3.46 −1.43 0.00 −0.85
Iran 50.60 30.12 39.48 9.23 10.82 201 127.50 161.76 17.15 33.15 0.40 0.08 0.24
Venezuela 50.10 18.07 33.19 11.23 15.61 202 171.57 187.61 5.93 14.73 0.60 0.17 0.46
Ghana 49.60 28.21 38.16 10.43 11.77 203 136.26 168.08 12.07 29.69 −1.70 0.41 −0.67
Sudan 49.40 26.91 37.13 9.68 11.62 204 141.42 173.39 13.11 29.82 0.00 0.42 0.05
Yemen 49.30 31.22 39.21 7.31 9.01 205 124.56 164.54 23.77 39.66 0.00 2.15 1.10
Myanmar 48.90 0.00 20.73 0.00 19.34 206 220.00 215.97 0.00 4.72 0.60 0.00 0.08
Senegal 49.00 22.03 34.57 10.97 13.73 207 159.76 183.51 6.69 21.27 0.70 0.38 0.68
Sierra Leone 47.50 20.80 32.91 9.36 12.78 208 163.15 187.22 12.84 22.75 −0.30 −0.32 −0.21
Clipperton Is 47.00 0.00 18.52 0.00 17.85 209 214.21 216.31 0.93 2.79 0.25 0.00 −0.05
Nigeria 46.60 0.00 21.79 0.00 19.18 210 216.31 213.41 0.46 2.92 1.60 0.00 0.65
Nicaragua 46.40 16.81 29.67 7.78 12.82 211 175.06 194.90 15.39 20.63 0.90 0.01 0.37
Somalia 45.80 26.26 35.18 9.06 10.44 212 143.71 178.46 16.26 32.43 −0.10 0.08 0.02
Angola 44.90 0.00 20.59 0.00 18.21 213 217.38 216.02 0.48 2.080 1.00 0.00 0.37
Pakistan 44.70 27.47 35.29 8.09 9.24 214 137.75 176.98 21.53 37.59 −0.70 −0.75 −0.71
Guinea 44.40 19.11 30.42 8.29 11.77 215 168.59 192.82 15.21 23.82 −0.60 0.37 −0.23
Ivory Coast 43.80 25.19 33.56 8.32 9.73 216 147.95 183.01 19.44 33.52 −0.70 −1.35 −1.03
Haiti 42.80 9.59 24.51 7.73 14.26 217 196.12 207.47 3.67 10.82 0.20 9.59 4.97
Liberia 41.90 22.12 30.88 8.22 9.95 218 158.52 189.79 18.52 30.21 −0.40 0.83 0.18
Demc Rep Congo 41.90 0.00 18.79 0.00 16.72 219 218.49 218.58 0.50 2.09 0.50 0.00 0.13
Guinea Bissau 41.10 18.83 28.76 7.69 10.52 220 169.01 195.43 17.15 26.2 −0.40 −1.48 −1.09

aThe ranking information for unlimited substitution potential in 2013 were obtained from www.oceanhealthindex.org and do not perfectly correspond to the ranking implied by the calculated ocean-health index values for (σ → ) in the second column. The ocean-health index values on the website are reported without post decimal positions.

The sensitivity of the ocean-health index to substitution possibilities is particularly apparent for countries with rather uneven ocean-health characteristics. Figure 2 shows the ocean-health index in dependence on substitution elasticity for five selected countries/islands. While both the Amsterdam and Saint Paul's Islands and Ile Europe have low to zero scores for $\sigma <1$, they improve their score significantly when substitution elasticity increases beyond 1. For high substitution elasticities they obtain a larger index value than New Zealand, Thailand, and the Falkland Islands, whose individual goal scores add up to less but are more evenly distributed among the goals. Despite the very poor performance of the Amsterdam and Saint Paul's Islands in 'Food Production' (with a value of 2) and of Ile Europa in the individual goal 'Sense of Place' (with a value of 0) in 2013, a concept of weak sustainability would cause their human-ocean system to be assessed as healthier than, for example, that of the Falkland Islands, which perform much better in their lowest individual goal score ('Food Production', with a value of 34).

Figure 2.

Figure 2. Ocean-health index dependent on substitution elasticity for selected countries.

Standard image High-resolution image

Consequently, accounting for the influence of the substitution possibilities is important when assessing sustainable development. Figure 3 shows the change in the overall ocean-health index between 2012 and 2013, again for weak sustainability (σ → ) and strong sustainability (σ ∼ U(0,1)). Of specific interest are those countries in the second and fourth quadrant in figure 2. The former shows those countries that have developed unsustainably in accordance with the concept of weak sustainability adopted by Halpern et al, but sustainably in accordance with a concept of strong sustainability. Among these 21 countries are prominent examples like Ghana, Canada or Australia. The fourth quadrant shows those countries that have developed sustainably in accordance with a concept of weak sustainability but unsustainably in accordance with a concept of strong sustainability. Among these 29 countries there are prominent examples like China, Brazil or South Africa.

Figure 3.

Figure 3. Comparison of change in the ocean-health index between 2012 and 2013 with unlimited substitution possibilities (weak sustainability) and with limited substitution possibilities (strong sustainability). Only the countries and islands in the second and fourth quadrants are indicated by name.

Standard image High-resolution image

4. Discussion and conclusion

The specification of the substitution possibilities cannot be derived from scientific research alone, but requires a normative foundation. Nevertheless, when dealing with such a variety of goals, all of which are essential for human well-being, the substitution possibilities should not be considered unlimited. Certainly, the goals defined by Halpern et al (2012) are interlinked by various biological relationships that reduce the probability of situations where certain goals deteriorate without affecting the health of other goals. However, these relationships are not fully understood, and the substantial score-spreads across goals among the countries indicate that various developments are not properly captured by biological relationships. Accordingly, we propose an alternative specification with substitution elasticity below 1 to allow for some degree of substitution but with a significant influence on the overall score by the least-performing goal.

Even though this approach satisfies a stronger sustainability concept, it is somewhat restrictive as it does not distinguish the substitution possibilities among the various goals. By contrast, it avoids any attempt to distinguish between the various goals to emphasize the importance of aggregation from a methodical perspective. However, there may be better substitution possibilities, for example, between goals like 'Coastal Livelihoods&#38;Economics' and 'Tourism&#38;Recreation' than between those goals and such an essential goal as 'Biodiversity'. We can deal with these varying degrees of substitution potential or individual goal significance by using a nested index or by introducing safe-minimum standards respectively. In its existing form, the ocean-health index already entails goals that summarize different sub-goals, here again, however, with unlimited substitution possibilities. In general, applying a nested index with various levels allows for consideration of different substitution possibilities at different levels by, for example, first aggregating capital stocks or goals with better substitution possibilities (Dovern et al 2014). Furthermore, safe-minimum standards for ecosystem services can be sustained by avoiding potential critical zones for the state of these ecosystems (Ciriacy-Wantrup 1952). Such minimum standards can easily be introduced by defining lower bounds for certain goals. The individual goal score would drop to zero if the goal falls short of this bound, and the overall score will also drop to zero if substitution elasticities are assumed to be below 1 (Heal 2009), albeit without dominating the index score if the state is still in good condition, which would in turn result from significantly increasing the weight of the goal.

The work by Halpern et al represents a seminal contribution to better understanding and management of the human-ocean system. However, precautionary and sustainable ocean governance makes it essential to properly account for the social evaluation of ocean benefits and for the various risks and uncertainties involved in our interaction with the ocean. Policy assessment and advice based on an index with unlimited substitution possibilities could result in (a) certifying a healthy human-ocean system for countries that in reality neglect important aspects of ocean health and (b) identifying development trajectories as sustainable although this is actually not the case. For that reason, we argue that significant attention should be devoted to the proper aggregation of data in assessing the health of the ocean.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Ben Halpern, Andrew Jenkins, and three anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. This research was conducted while Wilfried Rickels was a visiting scholar at the School of International Relations and Pacific Studies at the University of San Diego. Financial support has been provided by the German Research Foundation via Grant CP1108 within the Kiel Cluster of Excellence 'The Future Ocean', the German Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF) via grant 01LA1104C, and the Fritz Thyssen Foundation via grant Az.50.13.0.016.

Appendix:

Footnotes

  • 4  
  • 5  

    Detailed index and ranking information on all countries and islands with regard to the different specifications for the substitution possibilities in 2012 are available from the authors upon request.

Please wait… references are loading.
10.1088/1748-9326/9/4/044013