Letter The following article is Open access

Stranded nations? Transition risks and opportunities towards a clean economy

, , and

Published 31 March 2023 © 2023 The Author(s). Published by IOP Publishing Ltd
, , Focus on Technology and Global Change Citation Pia Andres et al 2023 Environ. Res. Lett. 18 045004 DOI 10.1088/1748-9326/acc347

Download Article PDF
DownloadArticle ePub

You need an eReader or compatible software to experience the benefits of the ePub3 file format.

1748-9326/18/4/045004

Abstract

The transition away from a fossil-fuel powered economy towards a cleaner production system will create winners and losers in the global trade system. We compile a list of 'brown' traded products whose use is highly likely to decline if the world is to mitigate climate change, and explore which countries are most at risk of seeing their productive capabilities 'stranded'. Using methods from economic geography and complexity, we develop novel measures of transition risk that capture the extent to which countries' export profiles are locked-in to brown products. We show that countries exporting a high number of brown products, especially technologically sophisticated ones, could find it relatively easy to transition. Conversely, countries with exports highly concentrated in a few, low-complexity brown products have much fewer nearby diversification opportunities. Our results suggest that export complexity and diversity play a key role in determining transition risk. Path-breaking diversification strategies are needed to prevent nations from becoming stranded.

Export citation and abstract BibTeX RIS

Original content from this work may be used under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 license. Any further distribution of this work must maintain attribution to the author(s) and the title of the work, journal citation and DOI.

1. Introduction

As the world transitions from dirty to clean energy sources and modes of production, some countries will be affected more than others. Previous research has explored which countries have the know-how, skills and innovative drive that makes them likely leaders in the 'race' towards green competitiveness (Fankhauser et al 2013, Mealy and Teytelboym 2020). However, there has been less work to better understand the characteristics of countries that could get left behind. Are all exporters of 'brown' (or emissions intensive) products likely to face significant transition risk, or are some brown export industries more challenging to transition from than others? While recent literature has studied transition risks to companies (e.g. Bolton and Kacperczyk 2021) and financial systems (e.g. Semieniuk et al 2021), quantitative estimates at the country-level are lacking. This paper fills this gap by estimating the degree to which countries' productive capabilities are 'locked-in' to sectors that are at risk of stranding.

A rich literature in economic geography has shown that industrial development in countries and regions is path dependent (Hausmann and Klinger 2006). Places are more likely to diversify into new activities that are similar to those they already have an advantage in (Hausmann and Klinger 2006, Frenken et al 2007, Hidalgo et al 2007, Neffke et al 2011). This, alongside the fact that exporting more technologically sophisticated products tends to be associated with higher income and growth (Hausmann et al 2007, Hidalgo and Hausmann 2009), has given rise to the 'Smart Specialization Policy' paradigm. The latter emphasizes place-based industrial policy which targets complex new economic activities that are also related to existing regional capabilities, thereby increasing the likelihood of success (Boschma and Gianelle 2013, Balland et al 2019). Path dependency implies that existing productive capabilities are important drivers of countries' ability to seize opportunities emerging in the green economy (Mealy and Teytelboym 2020). It also creates the potential for countries to be locked-in to brown industries, possibly resulting in stranded assets, stranded jobs and the risk of economic decline.

Fossil fuel resources may become effectively worthless as countries around the world take action to mitigate climate change (Caldecott 2015, Cust et al 2017), with significant implications for the companies and countries owning them. While the literature on asset stranding often focuses on carbon lock-in through long-lived physical infrastructure (e.g. Pfeiffer et al 2018, Fisch-Romito et al 2021), a broader definition beyond the risk to fossil fuel companies includes the risks to countries which are heavily dependent on fossil fuel exports, as well as workers whose skills are specific to declining activities (Van Der Ploeg and Rezai 2020). Country-level vulnerability to the transition will be governed both by their exposure to declining sectors, and their flexibility to adapt and change their economic structure accordingly (Zenghelis et al 2018).

Here, we quantify the degree to which countries' productive capabilities are tied up in declining sectors and identify viable transition paths, which is crucial to achieving a just transition. With the exception of Jee and Srivastav (2022), there has been limited research on this issue. Jee and Srivastav (2022) use patent data to show that direct knowledge spillovers between green and brown technologies are limited, but most green patents are connected to a brown patent through two or more degrees of separation. However, the ability of different energy-related inventions to build on one another need not directly translate into the ease with which a country's productive capabilities as a whole may transition to new activities. Moreover, mitigating transition risk need not require moving into green sectors, but rather moving out of brown ones.

We leverage methods introduced by Hidalgo et al (2007), Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009), and Mealy and Teytelboym (2020) to develop indicators of country-level lock-in to brown sectors and transition opportunities into activities which require similar capabilities. First, we compile a list of traded 'brown' products that are likely to see reduced global demand in a green economy. Drawing on the product space approach developed by Hidalgo et al (2007), we explore transition possibilities out of each brown product, and rank them in terms of their product complexity and transition outlook. While some products like coal or crude oil appear to have relatively limited diversification opportunities, other products such as engines, pumps and hydrocarbon-derived chemicals involve a wider variety of skills, capabilities and factors of production that could be used to diversify into other industries.

We then turn to countries and develop several novel metrics to explore the extent to which countries may be locked-in to brown exports. We show that countries exporting a high number of brown products, especially technologically sophisticated ones, may not only find it relatively easy to transition, but could also position themselves to play a key role in the production of green technologies and products. Conversely, countries with export baskets concentrated in few, low-complexity brown products have much more limited diversification opportunities into green or other exports. Their areas of specialization are heavily concentrated in the periphery of the product space, with few 'nearby' areas to move into. This is due to the peripheral location of extractive industries such as oil, gas and mining in the product space. Affected countries have few adjacent areas to move into and are therefore unlikely to adapt to a net zero future without policy to enable path-breaking diversification. Our findings are evocative of the 'resource curse' literature which emphasizes the difficulties resource-rich countries face in diversifying their economies (e.g. Krugman 1987, Manzano 2014, Sachs and Warner 1995).

Our results suggest that export complexity and diversity play a key role in mitigating transition risk and could potentially be more important than the 'brown-ness' of a country's export profile on its own. Early and pro-active policy interventions will likely be necessary to ensure a just and inclusive transition.

2. Method

2.1. Data

We construct our dataset using CEPII's BACI database (Gaulier and Zignago 2010), which is a global database of bilateral trade flows at the HS 6-digit level, spanning the period from 1995 to 2020. To ensure our results are not skewed by short-term trade fluctuations, we average country-product export values over 5-year periods. This results in a panel dataset of 5 distinct periods: 1996–2000, 2001–2005, 2006–2010, 2011–2015, and 2016–2020. Our panel includes 228 countries and territories. We collect control variables from the World Bank's World Development Indicators Database and OECD Stat's Environment Indicators 9 . Table 8 (appendix) displays summary statistics.

2.2. List of 'brown' products

We develop a new list of 'brown' products which are likely to decline in demand as the world decarbonizes. Because our focus is on economic competitiveness in a low carbon global economy, we focus on products which are brown in use rather than brown in production. We create a narrow and a broad list based on an initial keyword search on product descriptions and then validate these lists with key subject experts. We also draw on lists of green (Mealy and Teytelboym 2020) and CCS related (Serin et al 2021) products used in prior research. More detail about the construction of this list can be found in appendix A.

2.3. Measuring dependence on brown exports

The Green Complexity Index (GCI) introduced in Mealy and Teytelboym (2020) provides a measure of the degree to which countries are able to capitalize on the opportunities the green economy brings, by measuring their export competitiveness in technologically sophisticated green products. A key aim of this paper is to construct a 'brown' counterpart to the GCI: a measure of dependence on brown activities which provide fewer and fewer opportunities to the economy as the green transition progresses. Intuitively, the GCI is a complexity-weighted count of a country's competitive green exports. It therefore has a strong relationship with a country's diversity (the number of products exported competitively) and especially its green diversity (the number of green products exported competitively). Table 11 (appendix) documents this relationship.

When it comes to measuring brown lock-in, however, we find that countries which depend on brown products for a large share of their export value or export diversity tend to have low diversity overall. That is, major hydrocarbon exporters, for example, with up to 90% of export value composed of brown products, have few other competitive exports—including, in many cases, brown competitive exports, as brown diversity and overall diversity are in turn positively correlated (table 11, appendix). As Revealed Comparative Advantage (RCA) in brown exports for major fossil fuel exporters will in many cases be enormous, a binary measure of whether or not a country is competitive in brown products will not necessarily capture the degree of lock-in very well. On the other hand, exporting a large number of technologically sophisticated brown products implies that many pockets of competitiveness in high value-added activities are at risk of stranding. We therefore compute two indices capturing these different aspects of brown lock-in.

Our baseline measure of country lock-in to low-complexity, brown exports is the 'Brown Lock-in Index' (BLI), which we compute as:

Equation (1)

Here $\frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}$ is the share of each brown product in overall export values, and $\tilde{PCI}$ is the Product Complexity Index normalized to take a value between 0 and 1. Intuitively, the BLI measures the share of brown exports in a country's export volume, weighted by the inverse of PCI such that less technologically sophisticated products (which tend to be associated with lower income and growth compared to more complex ones, and open up fewer diversification paths) carry a larger weight.

We also construct a more obvious brown equivalent to the GCI: the Brown Complexity Index (BCI), calculated as

Equation (2)

where $\rho_b^c$ is a binary variable taking the value 1 if the country has RCA in brown product b, and 0 otherwise. This index counts the number of competitive brown exports, weighted by each product's complexity (as opposed to the BLI, which measures their share in exports and gives a greater weight to less complex brown products). Export capabilities in more technologically sophisticated activities may take longer to develop, involve more specialized equipment, and tend to bring greater benefits to the economy in terms of growth and income. On the other hand, countries with high overall complexity tend to have higher income, rendering them more adaptable to climate- and transition risks. Finally, more complex products are located in the denser core of the product space (see figure 1 for an illustration), implying a greater number of other, nearby diversification opportunities. Despite these benefits, countries must move out of brown areas of comparative advantage if we are to transition to a greener production system.

Figure 1.

Figure 1. Brown and green products in the product space.

Standard image High-resolution image

2.4. Measuring Transition Outlook

Due to the path dependency of industrial development, countries are more likely to develop future competitive advantages in products which require similar capabilities to the ones they already produce. Recall that Hidalgo et al (2007) measure the similarity or 'pairwise proximity' of two products as the probability that a country has RCA > 1 in one if it does in the other. We use this insight to develop measures aiming to capture the ease of transitioning out of brown activities.

While country proximity to non-brown products would be a measure of climate compatible diversification options more generally, there may be physical, institutional and human capital within a country which specializes in a declining sector and cannot easily transition into those new activities—in other words, even if activity in declining sectors were balanced out, or even exceeded, by new opportunities within the same country, the firms and individuals facing the highest transition risk may not be the same as those benefiting from opportunities in the green economy. We therefore aim to measure the proximity of each particular declining activity to other, climate compatible activities.

For each brown product, we compute the average proximity to products in a non-brown list (green or any non-brown), divided by the product's average proximity to all products, as follows:

Equation (3)

where $\Omega_{b,q}$ is the pairwise proximity between brown product b and climate-compatible (green or non-brown) product q; Q is the total number of products of type q; $\Omega_{b, p}$ is the pairwise proximity between product b and product p; and P is the set of all traded products.

We then compute the Country Transition Outlook as the average of product-level transition possibilities from brown products which the country exports with RCA > 1 to products in a non-brown list (green/any non-brown):

Equation (4)

where $\rho_b^c$ again indicates whether the country has RCA in product b, and TOb denotes the product's Transition Outlook to list q.

Indices are standardized to mean 0 and standard deviation 1. Table 7 (appendix) provides an overview over the measures we construct using trade data, some of which are derived from prior literature.

3. Results

3.1. Are brown products different from other exports?

Following the methodology originally used to create the product space (Hidalgo et al 2007), figure 1 plots the network of all products at the 6-digit level, highlighting those categorized as green or brown. In this network, traded products are represented as nodes, linked to each other on the basis of their product-to-product proximity. This provides some visual intuition for where green and brown products are located in the broader product space. Some brown products (such as conventional vehicles) are located within the dense core of the product space, close to many non-brown products, including green ones (such as electric or hybrid vehicles). Others, such as bovine meat or crude oil, are located in the periphery and mostly near other brown products. Petroleum is a particularly interesting case: while refined oil is arguably still within the core and near a good number of other products, crude oil is very peripheral. This would suggest that countries engaged in petroleum refining may find it easier to transition than those mostly exporting crude oil.

Overall, we find that brown products tend to be less complex than green products (see figure 2). We also find that brown products tend to be closer to green products in the product space than they are to other products. This suggests that countries which export these products may find it relatively easy to shift towards greener activities.

Figure 2.

Figure 2. Distribution of Product Complexity Index for brown products.

Standard image High-resolution image

Figure 2 plots the distribution of the Product Complexity Index (hereafter PCI) for products on our narrow brown list (in brown), compared to the distribution of PCI for all products (in blue). The PCI distribution for brown products is not statistically different to the PCI distribution for all products, suggesting brown products are no more or less complex than average 10 . Brown products thus tend to be less complex than green products, the latter on average being more complex than other products (Mealy and Teytelboym 2020).

Tables 13 and 14 (appendix) list the 20 brown products with the highest and the lowest PCI, respectively. Brown products which are high in complexity include engines, pumps and various hydrocarbon-derived chemicals, while low-complexity brown products more prominently feature unprocessed hydrocarbons.

Figure 3 plots the distribution of Product Transition Outlook to green products for the period 2016–2020. Transition opportunities for brown to green products tend to be above average, as indicated by the higher density of products with transition possibilities above 1. This suggests that there are proximate green transition opportunities for many brown exports.

Figure 3.

Figure 3. Distribution of Product Transition Outlook from brown to green products.

Standard image High-resolution image

Appendix D reports global trends in exports of brown and green products. We find that trade in brown products is currently much larger than trade in green products, but has declined slightly in recent years, while trade in green products shows a steady increase.

3.2. Country dependence on brown exports and transition possibilities

Our results indicate that countries which rely on low complexity brown products for a large share of their exports face very different challenges in the transition to those exporting more sophisticated brown products. For the latter group, we find that brown exports tend to be close to non-brown diversification opportunities in the product space. By contrast, the former group, and petrostates in particular, have low transition opportunities and could find it more difficult to adjust to a low carbon global economy.

Tables 1 and 2 show the 20 countries ranking most highly on the Brown Lock-in Index and Brown Complexity Index, respectively 11 . As we have alluded to, they paint two very different pictures. The countries ranking highest on the BLI include South Sudan, Iraq, and Libya, followed by a number of mostly other petrostates including Venezuela, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, and Iran.

Table 1. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Lock-in Index.

CountryBLIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
South Sudan3.5713.4994.82Not Available−4.42−2.71
Iraq3.48634.1294.505115.69−0.30−0.98
Libya3.29193.8990.925810.85−2.45−2.37
Angola3.27307.1388.993095.46−1.58−1.76
Equatorial Guinea3.2138.6288.808897.39−1.87−2.21
Azerbaijan3.19148.2089.414358.97−0.99−0.67
Nigeria3.18449.0587.692099.86−1.51−1.99
Brunei Darussalam3.0256.5591.5129 177.48−0.73−0.12
Chad2.9811.3081.44690.87−4.42−2.71
Venezuela2.92178.5184.28Not Available−0.31−0.74
Kuwait2.92479.8490.0029 599.34−0.75−0.63
Algeria2.91299.2393.753898.94−1.27−1.36
Qatar2.77571.7686.9858 919.32−1.71−0.99
Turkmenistan2.4971.4687.216888.55−0.17−0.98
Saudi Arabia2.421592.4174.1421 453.67−1.04−0.32
Timor-Leste2.250.6369.091385.77−2.05−0.35
Gabon2.1932.4164.237364.51−2.51−1.12
Oman2.16240.9769.6817 047.08−1.22−0.71
Kazakhstan2.09343.4363.789141.98−1.18−1.22
Iran1.99369.0163.003981.87−0.85−0.74

Note: The Brown Lock-in Index (BLI) constitutes our baseline measure of lock-in to brown exports. It is computed as $\textrm {BLI}_c = \Sigma_b \frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$ where $\frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}$ is the share of each brown product in overall export values, and $\tilde{PCI}$ is the Product Complexity Index normalized to take a value between 0 and 1. The table shows the 20 countries with the highest BLI.

Table 2. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Complexity Index.

CountryBCIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
USA4.932462.7417.1162 013.69−0.520.46
Japan4.271257.5018.6739 814.17−0.240.67
Germany3.951824.4913.2145 520.660.020.97
Belgium3.73460.6114.9245 068.76−0.410.33
Netherlands3.67718.2414.2650 490.97−0.440.09
France3.24468.568.9939 380.820.270.78
United Kingdom3.03802.3019.2942 026.79−0.050.88
Rep. of Korea2.84871.0115.4931 579.38−0.190.32
Thailand2.76321.7413.036977.580.070.41
India2.48488.1215.911947.720.43−0.05
Spain2.39534.7317.2728 314.840.140.02
Italy2.22434.858.7432 645.500.921.03
Austria2.02147.499.1148 550.290.301.22
China1.91652.102.609479.060.88−0.19
Poland1.67189.417.8714 646.760.740.63
Finland1.6298.5514.2447 483.980.541.37
Canada1.621269.6631.5244 725.29−0.850.28
Singapore1.61507.4916.8962 028.43−0.470.28
Turkey1.44222.4712.589719.310.800.17
Portugal1.4076.2311.8022 094.780.480.10

Note: The Brown Complexity Index (BCI) forms a direct counterpart to the Green Complexity Index (GCI) and measures the number and complexity of brown products a country is competitive in. It is computed as $\textrm {BCI}_c = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*\tilde{\textrm {PCI}}$. Export capabilities in more technologically sophisticated activities may take longer to develop and bring greater benefits to the economy. However, by opening up a greater number of diversification paths they are likely associated with easier transition pathways. The table shows the 20 countries with the highest BCI.

The BCI yields very different results. The country with the highest ranking of BCI, shown in table 2, is the United States, followed by Japan, Germany, and predominantly other industrialized nations, as well as emerging economies such as India and China. The BCI correlates positively with the GCI, indicating that countries which competitively export complex products, even if many of them are classed as 'brown', also tend to have strong capabilities to export complex green products. Table 11 (appendix) reports correlations between these and other indices.

Which countries enjoy proximate transition opportunities? Table 3 reports the results of a regression estimating the relationship

Equation (5)

where $\textrm {Index}_{c, t}$ denotes BLI, BCI or GCI, δt are year dummies, and ε is the error term. Standard errors are clustered at the country level 12 .

Table 3. Correlates of Country Transition Outlook measures.

 (1) Overall(2) Overall(3) Overall(4) Green(5) Green(6) Green
Brown Lock-in Index−0.518***  −0.573***  
(0.068)  (0.061)  
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)−0.051−0.028−0.0730.0910.049−0.014
(0.058)(0.066)(0.066)(0.066)(0.072)(0.062)
Coal rents (% of GDP)−0.066**−0.083**−0.083***−0.106***−0.128**−0.121**
(0.030)(0.038)(0.030)(0.034)(0.050)(0.054)
Oil rents (% of GDP)0.006−0.044***−0.038***0.006−0.040***−0.033***
(0.007)(0.004)(0.004)(0.006)(0.005)(0.004)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP)−0.021**−0.041**−0.038***0.001−0.015−0.013
(0.009)(0.016)(0.013)(0.011)(0.015)(0.012)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log)0.0420.065−0.0050.180*0.0490.055
(0.099)(0.114)(0.106)(0.107)(0.121)(0.104)
Brown Complexity Index −0.115***  0.244*** 
 (0.041)  (0.048) 
Green Complexity Index  0.082  0.365***
  (0.050)  (0.044)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations854854854854854854
R2.267.21.204.347.31.361

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.Dependent variables are country-level transition opportunities from brown to the list stated.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. Note: The table reports the results of a regression of Green and Overall Transition Outlook on the a number of potential explanatory variables.

Results indicate that the BLI is negatively and significantly associated with the ease of transitioning to green or overall non-brown products. The BCI is negatively associated with transition opportunities to non-brown products overall, but positively with transition opportunities to green products, which tend to be more complex.

We also explore the relationship between natural resource rents and $\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions and the ease of transitioning away from brown areas of competitive advantage. Most coefficients estimated are not statistically significant. Both coal and oil rents (as a % of GDP) seem to be negatively associated with transition possibilities (significant in most specifications), while natural gas rents are negatively associated with transition possibilities to non-brown products overall, but insignificant when it comes to transitioning to green. The coefficient on logged $\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions per capita is unstable, likely due to its relationship with some measures of brown and green competitiveness.

We carry out robustness checks computing our baseline measures of BLI and BCI for the longer list of brown products, which includes in particular cattle and sheep farming exports, as discussed in appendix A. Appendix E shows that our baseline results are broadly robust to this alternative definition of 'brown'.

3.3. Validation

We take several steps to ensure our measures are meaningful. First, we regress the Brown Lock-in Index and the Brown Complexity Index on a number of potentially relevant covariates, such as income, natural resource rents, and Revealed Technological Advantage 13 (RTA) in climate-relevant technologies. While there is no statistically significant relationship between the BLI and income, our results suggest high BCI-countries also have higher GDP per capita. The BLI is positively and significantly, the BCI negatively and significantly associated with higher oil rents. The BLI is also positively associated with natural gas rents and patenting in carbon capture and storage (CCS), but negatively with patenting in transport-related mitigation technologies. There is no significant association between BLI and per capita $\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions; however, countries which score highly in BCI have higher $\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions. By contrast, Mealy and Teytelboym (2020) find that countries with high green complexity have lower per capita emissions.

We also test the relevance of our Transition Outlook measures. We first regress BLI and BCI on lagged Green and Overall Transition Outlook, as well as their own lagged values, GDP per capita and other covariates. Results suggest that the Green Transition Outlook is a statistically significant predictor of future reductions in Brown Complexity Index, but not Brown Lock-in Index 14 . The Overall Transition Outlook, on the other hand, is significantly associated with reductions in future BLI but not BCI 15 .

Regression tables can be found in appendix B.

4. Discussion

Mitigating climate change requires a systemic technological transformation which is historically unparalleled in speed and scale. This transition is likely to leave large swaths of previously productive and profitable assets stranded. While the transition risk facing oil exporting countries has been noted (e.g. Manley et al 2017, Zenghelis et al 2018), quantitative measures of transition risk at the level of nations' productive structures have been lacking—a gap this paper has endeavored to fill. Our estimates of current lock-in to declining sectors, as well as the ease of transitioning to climate-compatible activities, highlight the isolated nature of extractive industries and the importance of diverse productive assets and capabilities in adapting to global economic shifts (Zenghelis et al 2018). We also map the similarity of brown products to green products within the product space, and find that many brown products seem to require similar productive capabilities as green products—in line with a recent finding by Jee and Srivastav (2022) that most clean patents are at least indirectly connected to a dirty patent in the technology space. This suggests many productive assets currently devoted to brown activities may shift to emerging green ones with relative ease. We find a similar pattern at the country level, with countries exporting a diverse number of sophisticated brown products often being well-positioned to shift into green technologies. Countries depending on a small number of fossil fuel exports, however, face significant transition risk.

There is an ongoing policy debate about transition opportunities for the fossil fuel industry. Suggested possibilities include green hydrogen and other low carbon fuels, ammonia, and products used in CCS. These tend to co-occur with high-carbon products, as $\textrm {CO}_2$ captured and stored with the respective technology can be utilized in a synthesis of methanol, for example (Collodi et al 2017). Hydrogen is primarily an energy carrier, which can be transformed to ammonia for easier transport, another net-zero relevant energy carrier. As the global market for hydrogen still needs to be scaled up, one can expect initially grey hydrogen to increasingly transform into blue and eventually green, as large-scale production facilities in countries such as Namibia, Morrocco, Chile and Australia come on-stream (Bouckaert et al 2021, Eicke and De Blasio 2022) 16 .

Our methodological approach has some potential to validate these largely anecdotal accounts. While the above considerations are mostly strategic and forward-looking, and trends in such directions therefore unlikely to feature prominently in historical data, there are some encouraging individual country examples. Saudi Arabia is the world's largest exporter of anhydrous ammonia 17 , accounting for 23% of world exports, followed by Russia and Trinidad and Tobago. Trinidad and Tobago and Saudi Arabia are further the largest exporters of methanol 18 at 13% of world exports each, followed by Iran at 11%. Drawing on the list of products related to carbon capture, utilization and storage (CCUS) compiled by Serin et al (2021), we find that declines (increases) in the share of refined oil, natural gas (liquefied or piped) and coal are all significantly associated with increases (reductions) in RCA in CCUS technologies, as well as—with the exception of LNG—export share of CCUS. There is, however, no correlation between changes in the share of crude and CCUS.

Despite these encouraging examples, however, our results highlight the limitations of exploiting 'latent comparative advantage' in countries which score highly on our Brown Lock-in Index measure. Countries which have reduced their BLI have tended to reduce reliance on coal or crude oil, but have usually done this either by increasing reliance on other hydrocarbon exports, like refined oil or natural gas, or by increasing exports of unrelated products. Pathways for 'related diversification' for these 'locked-in' countries are thus very limited. For example, the United Arab Emirates, whose BLI rank fell from 19 in 1996–2000 to 32 in 2016–2020, reduced the share of crude oil in its exports from 56.24% to 21.42% during the same period 19 . Meanwhile, the share of refined oil almost doubled, from 6.97% to 12.23%. The country further increased its exports of diamonds, metals and gold, jewellery and radio transmissions apparatus.

Overall, our results suggest that the complexity of a nation's exports could be more important to mitigating transition risk than the 'brown-ness' of those exports on its own. The related diversification approach is of limited use to countries which have few areas of latent comparative advantage in sectors that are likely to remain viable in the green economy. The question then becomes: how can countries break out of low complexity, low diversity specialization paths?

There is significantly less quantitative evidence on how regions may break out of path dependent trajectories than there is for the importance of relatedness in driving industrial development. Studies which do engage with this question suggest that the capacity to invest in innovation may play an important role in reducing the constraints of existing capabilities and enabling regions to jump into less related areas of specialization (e.g. Zhu et al 2017, Xiao et al 2018). Xiao et al (2018), in their study of Chinese regions' diversification into related and unrelated new industries over the period 2002–2011, further find a significant and positive effect of factors such as extra-regional linkages (proxied by FDI and imports), human capital and 'open-minded social-institutional contexts' in enabling regions to jump further within the industry space. This suggests that promoting extra-regional knowledge exchange and fostering healthy innovation ecosystems (see e.g. Gomes et al 2018, Brown and Mawson 2019, Leendertse et al 2021) may be key strategies for countries locked-in to low-complexity, declining industrial sectors.

5. Conclusion

This paper estimates the extent to which countries' productive capabilities are specialized in both complex and non-complex brown exports. We make three contributions to the literature. First, we develop novel measures of country-level transition risk that account for the ability of countries with brown exports to transition into more climate-compatible areas of comparative advantage. Second, we develop a list of traded 'brown' products, which provides a previously missing counterpart to the WTO's 'green' list used in prior research. Third, we locate declining brown products within the product space and measure their proximity to climate-compatible products.

Compared to the average exported product, brown products tend to be more proximate to green products. This is an encouraging finding, as it suggests that factors of production currently devoted to many brown activities could be redeployed towards climate compatible alternatives relatively easily. However, the picture is bleaker for major hydrocarbon exporters that score low on diversity, complexity, and have low proximity between their brown areas of comparative advantage and non-brown products within the product space. While smart specialization policies and relatedness measures can highlight the most proximate products for brown activities to shift into, this is less helpful for countries specialized in brown products at the periphery of the product space that have very few proximate diversification opportunities. As the difficulty fossil fuel exporters face in adapting to a low carbon future presents a threat to effective global climate action, there is an urgent need to find viable development pathways for these countries. Further research on how to achieve path-breaking diversification, particularly for low complexity regions, should be a high priority.

While our paper provides trade-based measures of transition risk and opportunities across nations, we recognize that transition risk will also vary within countries. Although our measures are agnostic regarding the underlying mechanisms of relatedness 20 , the ability of workers to move into new activities as some sectors decline is key to achieving a just transition. Existing research has examined the similarity of green skills to non-green skills (e.g. Consoli et al 2016, Saussay et al 2022). Saussay et al 2022 identify the skills intensities required for low- and high-carbon jobs using job ads data, and find evidence to suggest that differences between high- and low-carbon jobs tend to be smaller than those between generic and low-carbon jobs, but that high and low-carbon jobs in the US tend not to be spatially co-located. However, granular evidence on the transferability of skills used in declining sectors to climate compatible ones (green or not) is currently lacking and should be a priority for future research.

More broadly, our measures are based on historical patterns of co-exporting. The low carbon transition requires shifts in global trade, as well as changes in technologies themselves. Such dynamics are likely to transform the product space network and alter the relatedness between different economic activities. The implications of such changes in the network of economic activities for economic development are another important avenue for future inquiry.

Acknowledgments

We thank Joris Bücker, Theodor Cojoianu, Jim Cust, Aldo Ravazzi Douvan, Federico Drogo, Eugenie Dugoua, Marion Dumas, Roger Fouquet, Steve Jenkins, Martin Lokanc, Osmel Manzano, Misato Sato, and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments at various stages of this paper's development, as well as the participants of the seminars and workshops where this paper was presented and discussed. Pia Andres acknowledges funding from the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment at the London School of Economics, the ESRC Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) (reference ES/R009708/1), and the UK Foreign and Development Office through the Climate Compatible Growth Programme. Nils Handler acknowledges funding from the Foundation of German Businesses. Sam Fankhauser acknowledges funding from the UK Foreign and Development Office through the Climate Compatible Growth Programme.

Data availability statement

The data that support the findings of this study are available upon reasonable request from the authors. Data and additional country-specific figures and insights will also be made available at www.green-transition-navigator.org.

Appendix A: List of 'brown' products

To identify specializations in 'brown' products, we first define and identify such products within trade data, as no such list exists to date. Prior research analysing patenting trends in clean and dirty technologies has compiled various lists of dirty patent codes, which tend to focus primarily on the energy and transport sectors (e.g. Johnstone et al 2010, Verdolini and Galeotti 2011, Aghion et al 2016, Dechezleprêtre et al 2017, Popp et al 2020). Much of our list is in the spirit of this work. While the capacity to innovate is likely geographically correlated with production capabilities in a particular sector, exports are a more direct proxy of a country's actual manufacturing and other production capacity, as well as the jobs and capital tied up therein. They also have significant implications for overall economic viability and terms of trade. We therefore measure productive capabilities using export, rather than patent, data.

Since the goal of this paper is to assess transition risks and transition possibilities for countries, we focus specifically on developing a list of brown products for which global demand is likely to decline as the world decarbonizes. We maintain a focus on products which are mostly brown in use, rather than production. As such, we do not consider products where current production processes are polluting, but which can be expected to form part of the low carbon economy 21 . Moreover, our focus on the transition to a low carbon economy results in a narrower classification than a broader definition of 'brown' might.

We first conduct a keyword search on the descriptions of 6-digit codes within the Harmonized System 22 , aiming to create a 'narrow' and a 'broad' list. The narrow list focuses on fossil fuels and includes the following keywords: 'coal', 'petro', 'hydrocarbon', 'internal combustion engine', 'gas', 'combustion'. Fossil fuels are the biggest contributors to climate change, and their use must decline most substantially to reach net zero $\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions (Shukla et al 2019, 2022). The burning of coal, for example, accounts for 26% of global greenhouse gas emissions and needs to decline by 20%–70% by 2030 in order to reach the goals of the Paris agreement (Steckel and Jakob 2022), and coal consumption without CCS needs to fall by 67%–82% by 2030 to limit global warming to 1.5 C. Oil and gas consumption need to decline less abruptly. Overall, 30% of oil, 50% of gas and 80% of coal reserves are unburnable if we are to limit global warming to 2 C (Shukla et al 2022). Coal, oil and gas patents codes are also classified as dirty in the respective patent-literature (e.g. Aghion et al 2016, Dechezleprêtre et al 2017).

The broad list additionally includes the keywords 'bovine' (relating to cattle) and 'sheep'. Meat consumption, particularly beef and mutton, is particularly emission intensive and consumption reductions can reduce emissions substantially (Shukla et al 2019, Funke et al 2021). While they are brown in production, rather than in use, a more sustainable diet requires a shift away from these agricultural products. Hence we include both in our broader list, which is used for robustness checks.

To validate this keyword search-based classification into brown product categories and respective lists, we elicited feedback from five policy, chemicals and green innovation and growth experts. We approached experts based on their technical ability to assess the implications of the transition for relevant economic sectors. Whenever more than one expert disagreed with our classification, say to classify a product as brown, we followed that suggestion and reclassified the product. Upon cross-checking the proposed new list with the WTO's original green list we found that seven products to be moved to the brown list were on the WTO's list of green products and should therefore remain excluded. In the end, only one additional product was added to the brown list and another removed. We also matched our list to the green list used in prior research (Mealy and Teytelboym 2020) and excluded products which appeared on the brown and the green list from both lists. Following this validation process, 144 products constitute the narrow brown list vis-a-vis 171 products in the broad brown list. The revised green list includes 245 products, which includes CCUS products listed in Serin et al (2021).

We initially approached experts to also review a list of grey products designed to deal with controversial cases—specifically, the small set of products which appeared on both our brown and the WTO's green list, as well as steel, cement and plastic products. Steel, cement and plastic are particularly difficult cases to contend with: they are essential inputs into many sectors of the economy, including clean infrastructure. However, the emissions involved in their production process are very large, and not easily mitigated with available technology. Nevertheless, the fact that demand for some of these products such as cement and steel might increase as a result of the net zero transition, and that there was no clear rationale for including or excluding a product from the grey list given that most fossil-energy based production processes are polluting and need cleaning up, led us to eventually drop the list. Instead, we focus on brown goods which are both brown in use and likely to decline in demand in net zero scenarios.

There are many possible approaches which could be taken, such as selecting products based on embodied emissions (e.g. Broner et al 2012), and we therefore cannot claim this list to be exhaustive or authoritative. We have selected products which we consider uncontroversial in their status as 'highly likely to see demand declines in the green transition', as this approach is best suited to our aim of capturing transition risk. Other research on 'brown trade' (for example, work which focuses on exposure to carbon border adjustments) may be better served by a different list (for example, one which is based on embodied carbon emissions).

Appendix B: Validation

Table 4 reports our estimates of

Equation (6)

and

Equation (7)

where $\textrm {RTA}\_\textrm {Climate}_{c,t}$ is a vector of RTA values in climate-related technologies, δt are year dummies, and ε is the error term. Standard errors are clustered at the country level.

Table 4. Correlates of brown dependence measures.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BLI(4) BCI(5) BCI(6) BCI
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)0.045−0.0040.0570.321***0.180*0.204
(0.041)(0.049)(0.083)(0.055)(0.100)(0.159)
Coal rents (% of GDP) 0.035  0.008 
 (0.022)  (0.086) 
Oil rents (% of GDP) 0.090***  −0.025*** 
 (0.006)  (0.005) 
Natural gas rents (% of GDP) 0.036**  −0.017 
 (0.014)  (0.015) 
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log) 0.050  0.421*** 
 (0.098)  (0.159) 
RTA, Environment-related Technologies  1.939  1.271
  (1.198)  (1.809)
RTA, Energy-related Mitigation Technologies  −0.425  −3.280**
  (1.210)  (1.498)
RTA, Carbon Capture and Storage  3.658***  −4.977*
  (0.688)  (2.660)
RTA, Climate Change Adaptation Technologies  0.765  −1.061*
  (0.646)  (0.556)
RTA, Transport-related Mitigation Technologies  −2.525**  2.730
  (1.066)  (2.748)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations933854222933854222
R2.00453.767.203.212.324.171

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (narrow). Note: We regress the Brown Lock-in Index and the Brown Complexity Index on a number of potentially relevant covariates, such as income, natural resource rents, and Revealed Technological Advantage in climate-relevant technologies.

Table 5 reports our estimates of

Equation (8)

and

Equation (9)

while table 6 reports estimates of

Equation (10)

and

Equation (11)

where $X_{i,t-1}$ is a vector of controls, δt are year dummies, and ε is the error term. Standard errors are clustered at the country level.

Table 5. Predictive power of Green Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (t − 1)0.959***0.952***  
 (0.018)(0.034)  
Green Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.0020.003−0.024**−0.021**
 (0.019)(0.020)(0.009)(0.010)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)−0.003−0.0150.023***0.021
 (0.010)(0.016)(0.007)(0.017)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.026*** 0.002
  (0.009) (0.010)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.002 −0.001
  (0.003) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.004* −0.001
  (0.002) (0.001)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.023 0.020
  (0.027) (0.027)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.956***0.947***
   (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.931.943.926.93

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.t-1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Country Transition Outlook is calculated as $\textrm {Transition Outlook}_c = \frac{\Sigma_b \rho_b^c*\textrm {TO}_b}{\Sigma_b \rho_b^c}$, where $\rho_b^c$ indicates whether the country has RCA in product b, and $\textrm {TO}_b$ denotes the product's Transition Outlook to list q (more intuitively called Normalized Product Proximity). $\textrm {TO}_b = \frac{\Sigma_q^Q \Omega_{b, q}}{Q} / \frac{\Sigma_p^P \Omega_{b, p}}{P}$ with $\Omega_{b,q}$ being the pairwise proximity between brown product b and climate-compatible (green or non-brown) product q; Q the total number of products of type q; $\Omega_{b, p}$ the pairwise proximity between product b and product p; and P the set of all traded products. The table reports the results of a regression of the BLI and BCI on their lagged values, lagged Green Transition Outlook and several covariates, showing that a higher Green Transition Outlook predicts future decreases in BCI, but has no statistically significant association with BLI.

Table 6. Predictive power of Overall Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (${t}-1$)0.941***0.939***  
 (0.018)(0.030)  
Overall Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.042***−0.024*0.0050.010
 (0.016)(0.013)(0.009)(0.012)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)−0.005−0.0160.022***0.020
 (0.008)(0.016)(0.007)(0.017)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.025*** 0.005
  (0.009) (0.011)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.002 −0.000
  (0.003) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.004* −0.000
  (0.002) (0.001)
$\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.023 0.019
  (0.026) (0.027)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.948***0.943***
   (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.932.943.926.93

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 5, but using Overall, instead of Green, Transition Outlook.

Appendix C: Supplementary tables

Table 12 reports estimates of the relationships

Equation (12)

Equation (13)

Table 7. Measures derived from trade data.

NameFormulaSource
Revealed Comparative Advantage (RCA) $\textrm {RCA} = \frac{p_c}{\Sigma_p p_c} \big/ \frac{\Sigma_c p_c}{\Sigma_p \Sigma_c p_c}$ Balassa (1965)
Product-to-Product Proximity $\Omega_{p,p^{^{\prime}}}$ $= min\left(\frac{\Sigma \rho_p^c*\rho_{p^{^{\prime}}}^c}{\Sigma \rho_{p}^{c}}, \frac{\Sigma \rho_{p}^{c}*\rho_{p^{^{\prime}}}^{c}}{\Sigma \rho_{p^{^{\prime}}}^{c}}\right)$ Hidalgo et al (2007)
Country-to-Product Proximity $\omega_p^c = \frac{\Sigma_{p^{^{\prime}}}\rho_p^c*\Omega_{p,p^{^{\prime}}}}{\Sigma_{p^{^{\prime}}}\Omega_{p,p^{^{\prime}}}}$ Hidalgo et al (2007)
(Proximity Density)  
Diversity $\Sigma_p \rho_p^c $ Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009)
Economic Complexity Index (ECI)Eigenvector associated with the second largest right eigenvalue of the matrix given by $D^{-1}MU^{-1}M^{^{\prime}}$ where D is the diagonal matrix formed from the vector of countries' diversity values, U is the diagonal matrix formed from the vector of product ubiquity values and M is a binary matrix where rows correspond to countries, columns correspond to products and Mcp = 1 if country c's RCA in product p is > 1 and 0 otherwise.Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009)
Product Complexity Index (PCI)Eigenvector associated with the second largest right eigenvalue of the matrix given by $U^{-1}M^{^{\prime}}D^{-1}M$ Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009)
Green Complexity Index (GCI) $\textrm {GCI}_c = \Sigma_g \rho_g^c*\tilde{\textrm {PCI}}$ Mealy and Teytelboym (2020)
Brown Lock-in Index (BLI) $\textrm {BLI}_c = \Sigma_b \frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$ This Paper
Brown Complexity Index (BCI) $\textrm {BCI}_c = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*\tilde{\textrm {PCI}}$ This Paper
Brown Lock-in Index (binary) $\tilde{\textrm {BLI}_c} = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$ This Paper
Product Transition Outlook $\textrm {Transition Outlook}_b = \frac{\Sigma_q^Q \Omega_{b, q}}{Q} \big/ \frac{\Sigma_p^P \Omega_{b, p}}{P}$ This Paper
(Normalized Proximity)  
Country Transition Outlook $ \textrm {Transition Outlook}_c = \frac{\Sigma_b \rho_b^c*\textrm {TO}_b}{\Sigma_b \rho_b^c}$ This Paper

Note: Notation: $\frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}$ is the share of each brown product in overall export values. $\rho_p^c$ is a binary variable taking the value 1 if a country exports the product in question with RCA > 1. $\tilde{PCI}$ is the Product Complexity Index normalized to take a value between 0 and 1. $\Omega_{b,q}$ is the pairwise proximity between brown product b and climate-compatible (green or non-brown) product q; Q is the total number of products of type q; $\Omega_{b, p}$ is the pairwise proximity between product b and product p; and P is the set of all traded products.

Table 8. Summary statistics for trade and policy variables.

 meansdminmax
Brown Export Volume (1000 USD) $1.13 \times10^7$ $3.08 \times10^7$ 11.94 $2.88 \times10^8$
% Share of Brown in Export Volume19.9026.660.0799.70
Number of Competitive Brown Products11.8912.831.0076.00
% Share of Brown in Export Diversity3.454.670.1450.00
Green Export Volume (1000 USD) $3.95 \times10^6$ $1.74 \times10^7$ 0.00 $2.64 \times10^8$
% Share of Green in Export Volume3.183.520.0028.98
Number of Competitive Green Products24.4128.310.00163.00
% Share of Green in Export Diversity4.642.490.0016.67
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita)4.505.440.0042.74
GDP per capita (current USD)12 597.3518 127.71124.9311 6072.05
Coal rents (% of GDP)0.140.650.0010.63
Oil rents (% of GDP)3.799.430.0066.21
Natural gas rents (% of GDP)0.663.250.0057.32
RTA, Climate Change Adaptation Technologies0.681.270.0015.62
RTA, Energy-related Mitigation Technologies0.500.820.038.81
RTA, Environment-related Technologies0.810.870.085.38
RTA, Carbon Capture and Storage0.060.180.001.75
RTA, Transport-related Mitigation Technologies0.260.580.015.26
Observations1051   

Note: The table displays summary statistics for some of the indices we compute, as well as policy and control variables. Export-based indicators are computed using data from CEPII's BACI database (Gaulier and Zignago 2010). Revealed Technological Advantage (RTA) in different low carbon technologies is derived from OECD Stat. All other variables are collected from the World Bank's World Development Indicators.

Table 9. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Lock-in Index.

CountryBLIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
South Sudan3.5713.4994.82Not Available−4.42−2.71
Iraq3.48634.1294.505115.69−0.30−0.98
Libya3.29193.8990.925810.85−2.45−2.37
Angola3.27307.1388.993095.46−1.58−1.76
Equatorial Guinea3.2138.6288.808897.39−1.87−2.21
Azerbaijan3.19148.2089.414358.97−0.99−0.67
Nigeria3.18449.0587.692099.86−1.51−1.99
Brunei Darussalam3.0256.5591.5129 177.48−0.73−0.12
Chad2.9811.3081.44690.87−4.42−2.71
Venezuela2.92178.5184.28Not Available−0.31−0.74
Kuwait2.92479.8490.0029 599.34−0.75−0.63
Algeria2.91299.2393.753898.94−1.27−1.36
Qatar2.77571.7686.9858 919.32−1.71−0.99
Turkmenistan2.4971.4687.216888.55−0.17−0.98
Saudi Arabia2.421592.4174.1421 453.67−1.04−0.32
Timor-Leste2.250.6369.091385.77−2.05−0.35
Gabon2.1932.4164.237364.51−2.51−1.12
Oman2.16240.9769.6817 047.08−1.22−0.71
Kazakhstan2.09343.4363.789141.98−1.18−1.22
Iran1.99369.0163.003981.87−0.85−0.74
Br. Indian Ocean Terr.1.730.1654.42Not Available−0.900.33
Congo1.5349.6449.382208.69−2.32−1.19
Norway1.52580.7155.2874 254.91−0.90−0.42
Russian Federation1.472130.5457.9310 467.39−0.78−0.52
Yemen1.446.8946.56958.38−1.41−2.02
Trinidad and Tobago1.4046.0253.3116 305.01−1.61−1.34
Colombia1.38203.3354.266147.32−1.12−0.70
Bonaire1.130.1266.64Not Available−0.53−0.64
Cameroon1.1217.6440.521507.63−1.43−1.04
Papua New Guinea1.1141.8042.632716.75−1.55−1.87
Ecuador0.8872.1335.016078.49−0.92−0.60
United Arab Emirates0.84932.2041.4740 322.40−0.09−0.29
Aruba0.620.8339.6329 352.08−0.13−0.21
Curaçao0.603.6044.2819 018.16−0.37−0.69
Saint Vincent and the Grenadines0.590.6329.357277.430.52−0.32
Mozambique0.5524.9037.38469.77−0.90−1.56
Mongolia0.5425.9334.843993.63−0.82−1.76
Bolivia (Plurinational State of)0.5426.1931.543332.31−2.18−1.04
Myanmar0.5055.8929.301255.32−0.60−0.97
Australia0.48774.3030.9253 512.98−0.87−0.85
Togo0.469.4537.88868.740.950.12
Bahrain0.3543.9935.9822 879.850.13−0.33
Canada0.301269.6631.5244 725.29−0.850.28
Gibraltar0.281.0847.31Not Available−0.171.59
Ghana0.2634.8219.782151.85−0.93−0.46
Dem. People's Rep. of Korea0.223.1829.77Not Available0.570.61
Egypt0.2276.9122.343017.92−0.34−0.44
Greece0.16100.1528.8418 590.330.34−0.42
Maldives0.130.5721.769310.320.01−0.42
Sudan0.127.5516.78783.89−2.48−2.37

Note: The Brown Lock-in Index (BLI) constitutes our baseline measure of lock-in to brown exports. It is computed as $\textrm {BLI}_c = \Sigma_b \frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$ where $\frac{\textrm {exports}_b}{\Sigma_p \textrm {exports}_p}$ is the share of each brown product in overall export values, and $\tilde{PCI}$ is the Product Complexity Index normalized to take a value between 0 and 1. The table shows the 50 countries with the highest BLI.

Table 10. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Complexity Index.

CountryBCIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
USA4.932462.7417.1162 013.69−0.520.46
Japan4.271257.5018.6739 814.17−0.240.67
Germany3.951824.4913.2145 520.660.020.97
Belgium3.73460.6114.9245 068.76−0.410.33
Netherlands3.67718.2414.2650 490.97−0.440.09
France3.24468.568.9939 380.820.270.78
United Kingdom3.03802.3019.2942 026.79−0.050.88
Rep. of Korea2.84871.0115.4931 579.38−0.190.32
Thailand2.76321.7413.036977.580.070.41
India2.48488.1215.911947.720.43−0.05
Spain2.39534.7317.2728 314.840.140.02
Italy2.22434.858.7432 645.500.921.03
Austria2.02147.499.1148 550.290.301.22
China1.91652.102.609479.060.88−0.19
Poland1.67189.417.8714 646.760.740.63
Finland1.6298.5514.2447 483.980.541.37
Canada1.621269.6631.5244 725.29−0.850.28
Singapore1.61507.4916.8962 028.43−0.470.28
Turkey1.44222.4712.589719.310.800.17
Portugal1.4076.2311.8022 094.780.480.10
Hungary1.34165.0514.3115 374.970.361.45
Russian Federation1.312130.5457.9310 467.39−0.78−0.52
Czechia1.26220.9011.8821 844.520.631.11
Indonesia1.25392.9021.413859.81−0.52−0.46
Slovenia1.2138.8510.9724 536.800.891.35
United Arab Emirates1.07932.2041.4740 322.40−0.09−0.29
South Africa1.05177.8816.756346.73−0.240.10
Saudi Arabia1.031592.4174.1421 453.67−1.04−0.32
Sweden1.01214.5314.0752 911.910.521.56
Brazil0.95314.5614.478696.90−0.580.01
Iran0.92369.0163.003981.87−0.85−0.74
Slovakia0.91202.4123.4318 389.280.081.13
Mexico0.84959.8422.139199.810.261.74
Romania0.8165.128.6811 710.000.300.95
Lithuania0.8043.6814.1018 165.610.410.76
Grenada0.670.013.8110 067.390.611.06
Belarus0.6671.8724.716089.46−0.070.48
Israel0.6229.404.9941 657.61−0.120.13
Denmark0.6150.995.1458 941.020.710.91
Philippines0.5216.981.993246.640.40−0.29
Brunei Darussalam0.4956.5591.5129 177.48−0.73−0.12
Oman0.48240.9769.6817 047.08−1.22−0.71
Ukraine0.4311.922.423061.800.520.23
Norway0.40580.7155.2874 254.91−0.90−0.42
Argentina0.3978.1213.0711 566.82−0.77−0.20
Latvia0.359.556.4716 697.550.400.05
Egypt0.3376.9122.343017.92−0.34−0.44
Guam0.310.025.7836 407.51−0.060.17
Cyprus0.277.6716.6327 456.57−0.02−0.07
Serbia0.2513.927.346889.570.540.91

Note: The Brown Complexity Index (BCI) forms a direct counterpart to the Green Complexity Index (GCI) and measures the number and complexity of brown products a country is competitive in. It is computed as $\textrm {BCI}_c = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*\tilde{\textrm {PCI}}$. Export capabilities in more technologically sophisticated activities may take longer to develop and bring greater benefits to the economy. However, by opening up a greater number of diversification paths they are likely associated with easier transition pathways. The table shows the 50 countries with the highest BCI.

Table 11. Key relationships.

Variable 1Variable 2Correlation
Brown Complexity IndexBrown Diversity Share0.04
Brown Complexity IndexBrown Export Diversity0.99
Brown Complexity IndexBrown Export Share (%)0.00
Brown Complexity IndexDiversity0.78
Brown Complexity IndexEconomic Complexity Index0.62
Brown Complexity IndexGDP per capita (USD)0.39
Brown Complexity IndexGreen Complexity Index0.80
Brown Diversity ShareDiversity−0.26
Brown Export DiversityDiversity0.77
Brown Export Share (%)Diversity−0.25
Brown Lock-in IndexBrown Diversity Share0.72
Brown Lock-in IndexBrown Export Diversity0.00
Brown Lock-in IndexBrown Export Share (%)0.98
Brown Lock-in IndexDiversity−0.30
Brown Lock-in IndexEconomic Complexity Index−0.33
Brown Lock-in IndexGDP per capita (USD)−0.03
Brown Lock-in IndexGreen Complexity Index−0.25
Green Complexity IndexDiversity0.88
Green Complexity IndexGreen Export Diversity0.99
Green Export DiversityDiversity0.90

Note: The table shows correlation coefficients between our key indices, as well as the indices and other relevant measures such as export diversity and GDP per capita.

Table 12. Changes in the relative share of carbon capture and storage technologies.

 (1) ΔExport Share(2) ΔRCA
Δ Export Share, Refined (%)−0.005*−0.005*
 (0.003)(0.003)
Δ Export Share, Natural Gas (%)−0.004**−0.004**
 (0.002)(0.002)
Δ Export Share, LNG (%)−0.003−0.003*
 (0.002)(0.002)
Δ Export Share, Coal (%)−0.017***−0.016***
 (0.005)(0.004)
Δ Export Share, Crude (%)−0.000−0.000
 (0.002)(0.002)
Year FEsYesYes
Observations823823
R2.005 99.004 57

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Dependent variables relate to carbon capture and storage.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Note: The table reports results of a linear regression of changes in the export share and Revealed Comparative Advantage in CCUS products on changes in the shares of selected fossil fuels. Standard errors are clustered at the country level.

where δt are year dummies, and ε is the error term. Standard errors are clustered at the country level.

Appendix D: Supplementary figures

Products on our brown list account for a significantly larger share of global trade than green products. However, our results suggest that trade in brown products declined somewhat in the last period (2016–2020) compared to the penultimate period (2011–2015). Figure 4 indicates that 'brown' trade peaked at close to 40 billion USD (about 22% of global trade) during the 2011–2015 period and declined slightly thereafter. While this may be partly attributable to the global covid-19 pandemic, it is noteworthy that volumes of green trade continued to rise during the same time period.

Figure 4.

Figure 4. Global trends in green and brown trade.

Standard image High-resolution image

Figure 5 plots the top 10 exporters in terms of trade values for green and brown products. Strikingly, China rose to the top of this ranking for green products during the early 2000s, but does not appear within the top 10 exporters of brown products—unlike the United States, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, Canada, South Korea and Mexico, all of which appear alongside petrostates such as Russia, Saudi Arabia and the UAE.

Figure 5.

Figure 5. Top 10 exporters of green and brown products.

Standard image High-resolution image

Table 13 lists the 20 brown products with the highest PCI and their descriptions, while table 14 shows those with the lowest PCI. Brown products which are high in complexity include engines, pumps and various hydrocarbon-derived chemicals, while low-complexity brown products more prominently feature unprocessed hydrocarbons.

Table 13. Top 20 brown products in terms of PCI.

HS 1992DescriptionPCITransition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
290270Cyclic hydrocarbons; cumene1.750.991.08
290323Unsaturated chlorinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons; tetrachloroethylene (perchloroethylene)1.660.991.22
340319Lubricating preparations; (other than for the treatment of textile and similar materials), containing less than 70% (by weight) of petroleum oils or oils obtained from bituminous minerals1.621.001.40
290314Saturated chlorinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons; carbon tetrachloride1.591.001.07
391110Petroleum resins, coumarone, indene or coumarone-indene resins and polyterpenes; in primary forms1.531.001.14
840790Engines; rotary internal combustion piston engines, for other than aircraft or marine propulsion1.411.001.17
270720Oils and products of the distillation of high temperature coal tar; toluole1.410.991.06
870323Vehicles; spark-ignition internal combustion reciprocating piston engine, cylinder capacity exceeding 1500 cc but not exceeding 3000 cc1.410.991.50
290123Acyclic hydrocarbons; unsaturated, butene (butylene) and isomers thereof1.380.991.15
290313Saturated chlorinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons; chloroform (trichloromethane)1.370.991.17
290315Saturated chlorinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons; 1,2-dichloroethane (ethylene dichloride)1.360.991.15
841690Furnaces; parts of furnace burners, for liquid fuel, pulverized solid fuel or gas, mechanical stokers, grates, ash dischargers and the like1.311.001.44
840820Engines; compression-ignition internal combustion piston engines (diesel or semi-diesel engines), of a kind used for the propulsion of vehicles of chapter 871.271.001.39
290312Saturated chlorinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons; dichloromethane (methylene chloride)1.271.001.17
840890Engines; compression-ignition internal combustion piston engines (diesel or semi-diesel engines), of a kind used for other than marine propulsion or the vehicles of chapter 871.271.001.43
841620Furnaces; furnace burners, for pulverized solid fuel or gas, including combination burners1.231.001.47
290260Cyclic hydrocarbons; ethylbenzene1.220.991.26
270730Oils and products of the distillation of high temperature coal tar; xylole1.210.991.03
290330Fluorinated, brominated or iodinated derivatives of acyclic hydrocarbons1.210.991.11
290361Halogenated derivatives of aromatic hydrocarbons; chlorobenzene, o-dichlorobenzene and p-dichlorobenzene1.171.001.07

Note: The table lists the 20 products with the highest PCI across the (narrow) brown list.

Table 14. Bottom 20 brown products in terms of PCI.

HS 1992DescriptionPCITransition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
270900Oils; petroleum oils and oils obtained from bituminous minerals, crude−2.600.980.89
271111Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; liquefied, natural gas−2.290.990.82
271129Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; in gaseous state, other than natural gas−2.141.000.90
271121Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; in gaseous state, natural gas−1.790.980.81
271119Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; liquefied, n.e.s. in heading no. 2711−1.740.990.95
270119Coal; (other than anthracite and bituminous), whether or not pulverised but not agglomerated−1.620.990.83
270500Gases; coal, water, producer and similar gases (excluding petroleum and other gaseous hydrocarbons)−1.591.001.03
271113Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; liquefied, butanes−1.580.991.08
271112Petroleum gases and other gaseous hydrocarbons; liquefied, propane−1.490.980.97
270740Oils and products of the distillation of high temperature coal tar; naphthalene−1.411.001.08
270112Coal; bituminous, whether or not pulverised, but not agglomerated−1.300.980.96
870432Vehicles; spark-ignition internal combustion piston engine, for transport of goods, (of a g.v.w. exceeding 5 tonnes), nes in item no 8704.1−1.291.001.33
271311Petroleum coke; (not calcined), obtained from bituminous minerals−1.260.990.97
270111Coal; anthracite, whether or not pulverised, but not agglomerated−1.041.000.86
840710Engines; for aircraft, spark-ignition reciprocating or rotary internal combustion piston engines−0.991.001.02
271210Petroleum jelly−0.881.001.10
271000Oils; petroleum oils and oils obtained from bituminous minerals, not crude; preparations n.e.s., containing by weight 70% or more of petroleum oils or oils obtained from bituminous minerals−0.821.001.07
850212Electric generating sets; with compression-ignition internal combustion piston engines (diesel or semi-diesel engines), of an output exceeding 75 kva but not exceeding 375 kva−0.811.001.02
850213Electric generating sets; with compression-ignition internal combustion piston engines (diesel or semi-diesel engines), of an output exceeding 375 kva−0.791.001.11
843039Coal or rock cutters and tunnelling machinery; not self-propelled−0.661.001.36

Note: The table lists the 20 products with the lowest PCI across the brown (narrow) list.

Appendix E: Extension: long list of brown products

Table 15. Correlates of brown dependence measures.

 (1) BLI (Full)(2) BLI (Full)(3) BLI (Full)(4) BCI (Full)(5) BCI (Full)(6) BCI (Full)
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)0.078*−0.0560.0680.325***0.219**0.216
 (0.041)(0.066)(0.079)(0.054)(0.098)(0.165)
Coal rents (% of GDP) 0.006  0.047 
  (0.032)  (0.089) 
Oil rents (% of GDP) 0.070***  −0.026*** 
  (0.006)  (0.005) 
Natural gas rents (% of GDP) 0.050**  −0.019 
  (0.024)  (0.015) 
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log) 0.228*  0.366** 
  (0.127)  (0.158) 
RTA, Environment-related Technologies  1.661  1.029
   (1.114)  (1.660)
RTA, Energy-related Mitigation Technologies  −0.500  −3.077**
   (1.133)  (1.412)
RTA, Carbon Capture and Storage  3.476***  −4.730*
   (0.711)  (2.533)
RTA, Climate Change Adaptation Technologies  0.805  −1.070*
   (0.676)  (0.555)
RTA, Transport-related Mitigation Technologies  −2.500**  2.399
   (0.992)  (2.627)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations933854222933854222
R2.0139.659.186.22.347.191

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (broad). Note: Like table 4, but using the long list of brown products.

Table 16. Predictive power of Green Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI (Full)(2) BLI (Full)(3) BCI (Full)(4) BCI (Full)
Brown Lock-in Index (full list, t − 1)0.915***0.906***  
 (0.025)(0.031)  
Green Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.028−0.011−0.018*−0.013
 (0.020)(0.021)(0.010)(0.011)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)0.007−0.0050.025***0.025
 (0.010)(0.018)(0.007)(0.018)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.028** −0.001
  (0.014) (0.009)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.005** −0.001
  (0.002) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.010*** −0.001
  (0.003) (0.001)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.023 0.020
  (0.029) (0.028)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.950***0.938***
   (0.014)(0.015)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.86.884.922.926

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (broad). t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 5, but using the long list of brown products.

Table 17. Predictive power of overall Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI (Full)(2) BLI (Full)(3) BCI (Full)(4) BCI (Full)
Brown Lock-in Index (full list, t − 1)0.902***0.901***  
 (0.024)(0.030)  
Overall Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.060***−0.029*0.0060.009
 (0.019)(0.017)(0.009)(0.012)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)0.000−0.0070.024***0.024
 (0.008)(0.018)(0.007)(0.018)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.027** 0.001
  (0.013) (0.010)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.004** −0.000
  (0.002) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.009*** −0.000
  (0.003) (0.001)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log, $t-1$) 0.021 0.018
  (0.029) (0.028)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.945***0.937***
   (0.014)(0.015)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.862.884.922.926

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (broad). t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 6, but using the long list of brown products.

Appendix F: Extension: alternative BLI using binary RCA

As an extension of our baseline analysis, we compute the Brown Lock-in Index using binary RCA, instead of product shares in country exports. This alternative version of BLI is calculated as

Equation (14)

This is a more direct inverse of the GCI: it is computed in exactly the same manner, but using brown instead of green products and attributing greater weight to less, rather than more, complex products. The index is positively associated with overall export diversity and a larger number of diversification paths, making our baseline BLI the preferred measure for brown lock-in.

Our key result here is that when BLI is computed in this manner, it displays a strong positive correlation to BCI—which, as we have shown, correlates positively with GCI, a relationship apparently driven by higher export diversity and the 'weighted count' nature of these indices. Figure 6 plots our baseline and alternative measures of BLI against the BCI, underscoring this finding. The correlation between BCI and the alternative measure of BLI indicates that the weighting by either PCI or inverse PCI plays a secondary role to the diversity aspect (the number of competitive exports within a product group) when a country's rank is computed. Countries with an unusually high share of brown exports in overall export volumes tend to have low export diversity, including within the group of brown products, as well as low export complexity. In contrast, countries which score high on our alternative BLI or BCI measures export a greater number of brown products with RCA > 1, and the ranking of countries is similar regardless of whether we give a higher relative weight to products with high or low complexity, as tables 10 and 18 show. In both cases, the United States score most highly and a number of industrialized countries feature among the top 20 countries. However, some petrostates—such as Russia, the UAE, Saudi Arabia and Iran—score highly on our alternative BLI, but not BCI, suggesting that these countries export a variety of low-complexity brown products, but not high-complexity ones.

Figure 6.

Figure 6. Baseline and alternative measures of BLI, plotted against BCI.

Standard image High-resolution image

Table 18. Alternative BLI top 20.

CountryGDP per capita [USD]BLI (binary)Brown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
USA62 013.694.392462.7417.11−0.520.46
India1947.722.93488.1215.910.43−0.05
Spain28 314.842.89534.7317.270.140.02
Japan39 814.172.861257.5018.67−0.240.67
Russian Federation10 467.392.692130.5457.93−0.78−0.52
Netherlands50 490.972.65718.2414.26−0.440.09
United Kingdom42 026.792.53802.3019.29−0.050.88
Belgium45 068.762.53460.6114.92−0.410.33
United Arab Emirates40 322.402.48932.2041.47−0.09−0.29
France39 380.822.32468.568.990.270.78
Germany45 520.662.311824.4913.210.020.97
Thailand6977.582.12321.7413.030.070.41
Indonesia3859.812.09392.9021.41−0.52−0.46
Canada44 725.292.061269.6631.52−0.850.28
Turkey9719.311.94222.4712.580.800.17
Rep. of Korea31 579.381.94871.0115.49−0.190.32
Saudi Arabia21 453.671.831592.4174.14−1.04−0.32
Iran3981.871.82369.0163.00−0.85−0.74
South Africa6346.731.77177.8816.75−0.240.10
Italy32 645.501.77434.858.740.921.03

Note: The Brown Lock-in Index is here computed as $\tilde{\textrm {BLI}_c} = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$.

Table 19. Correlates of brown dependence measures.

 (1) BLI (binary)(2) BLI (binary)(3) BLI (binary)(4) BCI(5) BCI(6) BCI
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)0.297***0.0400.0700.321***0.180*0.204
 (0.047)(0.090)(0.153)(0.055)(0.100)(0.159)
Coal rents (% of GDP) 0.049  0.008 
  (0.127)  (0.086) 
Oil rents (% of GDP) −0.011**  −0.025*** 
  (0.005)  (0.005) 
Natural gas rents (% of GDP) −0.016  −0.017 
  (0.016)  (0.015) 
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log) 0.636***(0.145)   0.421***(0.159)  
RTA, Environment-related Technologies  0.926  1.271
   (1.792)  (1.809)
RTA, Energy-related Mitigation Technologies  −2.166(1.398)   −3.280**(1.498)
RTA, Carbon Capture and Storage  −3.453  −4.977*
   (2.370)  (2.660)
RTA, Climate Change Adaptation Technologies  −0.564 (0.595)   −1.061* (0.556)
RTA, Transport-related Mitigation Technologies  0.261 (2.101)   2.730 (2.748)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations933854222933854222
R2.194.32.0924.212.324.171

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (narrow). Note: Like table 4, except that the Brown Lock-in Index is here computed as $\tilde{\textrm {BLI}_c} = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$.

Tables 20 and 21 show that our Transition Outlook measures are not predictive of future changes in binary BLI.

Table 20. Predictive power of Green Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI (binary)(2) BLI (binary)(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (binary RCA, t − 1)0.895***0.880***  
 (0.022)(0.024)  
Green Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.016−0.001−0.024**−0.021**
 (0.013)(0.014)(0.009)(0.010)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)0.039***0.037*0.023***0.021
 (0.011)(0.022)(0.007)(0.017)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.029 0.002
  (0.019) (0.010)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.001 −0.001
  (0.001) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.001 −0.001
  (0.002) (0.001)
$\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.023 0.020
  (0.037) (0.027)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.956***0.947***
   (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.843.849.926.93

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 5, except that the Brown Lock-in Index is here computed as $\tilde{\textrm{BLI}_c} = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$.

Table 21. Predictive power of overall Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI (binary)(2) BLI (binary)(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (binary RCA, t − 1)0.891***0.881***  
 (0.022)(0.024)  
Overall Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.0090.0030.0050.010
 (0.013)(0.017)(0.009)(0.012)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)0.037***0.037*0.022***0.020
 (0.011)(0.022)(0.007)(0.017)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.029 0.005
  (0.019) (0.011)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.001 −0.000
  (0.001) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.001 −0.000
  (0.002) (0.001)
$\textrm {CO}_2$ emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.023 0.019
  (0.037) (0.027)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.948***0.943***
   (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations715661715661
R2.843.849.926.93

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 6, except that the Brown Lock-in Index is here computed as $\tilde{\textrm {BLI}_c} = \Sigma_b \rho_b^c*(1 - \tilde{\textrm {PCI}})$.

Table 22. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Lock-in Index.

CountryBLIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
Iraq3.43635.0694.345115.69−0.48−0.83
South Sudan3.3713.4991.06Not Available−4.67−2.71
Libya3.26195.4590.715810.85−2.46−2.57
Angola3.20307.4787.873095.46−1.74−1.95
Equatorial Guinea3.1838.6887.988897.39−2.15−2.38
Azerbaijan3.16148.2588.814358.97−1.00−0.72
Nigeria3.11449.4486.352099.86−1.49−2.15
Brunei Darussalam2.9360.4291.2529 177.48−0.81−0.16
Algeria2.92301.8293.263898.94−1.47−1.45
Chad2.8911.3080.07690.87−4.67−2.71
Kuwait2.86481.1988.8529 599.34−1.14−0.73
Venezuela2.82178.8682.68Not Available−0.35−0.80
Qatar2.81571.8686.5658 919.32−1.63−0.92
Br. Indian Ocean Terr.2.560.7773.49Not Available−0.870.13
Turkmenistan2.5271.5883.746888.55−0.20−1.10
Saudi Arabia2.391595.3974.0521 453.67−1.13−0.42
Gabon2.1332.4363.377364.51−2.15−0.97
Oman2.12241.7068.8117 047.08−1.26−0.80
Kazakhstan2.07344.2863.609141.98−1.40−1.05
Iran1.97375.7163.133981.87−0.91−0.85
Timor-Leste1.870.7762.431385.77−2.11−0.42
Norway1.56580.7955.2574 254.91−0.99−0.53
Bonaire1.550.4478.77Not Available−0.77−0.71
Congo1.4949.6948.832208.69−1.59−0.83
Russian Federation1.462130.5457.9110 467.39−0.87−0.50
Trinidad and Tobago1.4346.6653.3816 305.01−1.57−1.78
Colombia1.37203.3854.136147.32−1.20−0.74
Yemen1.377.0245.37958.38−1.33−2.17
Papua New Guinea1.1442.1242.482716.75−1.76−1.96
Cameroon1.1319.0441.271507.63−1.61−1.06
Guyana1.0911.7538.826329.52−2.10−1.03
Ecuador0.8572.1834.896078.49−0.96−0.67
United Arab Emirates0.82932.2041.4640 322.40−0.19−0.33
Dem. People's Rep. of Korea0.677.5738.52Not Available0.450.17
Curaçao0.624.0244.3019 018.16−1.12−0.93
Myanmar0.6161.4730.681255.32−0.83−0.80
Bolivia (Plurinational State of)0.5926.1931.263332.31−2.06−1.41
Mozambique0.5524.9836.21469.77−0.78−1.31
Mongolia0.5325.9634.383993.63−1.08−1.78
Australia0.50774.3130.8953 512.98−0.95−0.86
Aruba0.471.1533.8429 352.08−0.21−0.33
Togo0.439.4737.42868.740.96−0.21
Maldives0.420.9329.469310.320.12−0.60
Saint Vincent and the Grenadines0.390.6423.997277.430.13−0.25
American Samoa0.320.2427.3911 824.79−0.26−0.71
Bahrain0.3144.1235.4022 879.850.08−0.51
Canada0.281269.6731.5144 725.29−0.920.34
Ghana0.2434.8419.652151.85−0.680.24
Egypt0.2278.7522.673017.92−0.49−0.75
Greece0.14100.1828.8218 590.330.14−0.52

Note: Like table 9, but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Appendix G: Extension: alternative averaging procedure

The BACI database only records strictly non-negative trade flows to save space. For this reason we assume that missing exporter-year-product observations are 0 and include these in the 5-year averages used in our baseline estimates. As a robustness check, we also compile an alternative dataset in which missing exporter-year-product observations are treated as missing. This section reports key results using this procedure and shows that our country rankings and key regression results change only very marginally when doing so.

Table 23. Countries ranking most highly on the Brown Complexity Index.

CountryBCIBrown exports [1M USD]Brown Export Share [%]GDP per capita [USD]Transition OutlookGreen Transition Outlook
USA4.972462.7417.1162 013.69−0.560.51
Japan4.271257.5018.6739 814.17−0.250.73
Germany3.931824.4913.2045 520.66−0.041.05
Belgium3.78460.6114.9045 068.76−0.480.39
Netherlands3.64718.2414.2550 490.97−0.510.09
France3.28468.568.9839 380.820.190.83
United Kingdom3.04802.3019.2842 026.79−0.150.90
Rep. of Korea2.80871.0115.4931 579.38−0.240.34
Thailand2.80321.7413.026977.58−0.010.49
India2.39488.1215.911947.720.24−0.07
Italy2.33434.908.7432 645.500.831.18
Spain2.29534.7317.2628 314.840.120.03
Austria2.02147.499.1048 550.290.231.31
China1.74652.102.609479.060.77−0.06
Poland1.66189.417.8714 646.760.690.69
Canada1.621269.6731.5144 725.29−0.920.34
Finland1.5898.5614.2247 483.980.511.45
Singapore1.57507.5216.8862 028.43−0.520.30
Turkey1.43222.4712.589719.310.730.19
Portugal1.3876.2411.8022 094.780.400.11
Hungary1.37165.0614.3015 374.970.311.58
Czechia1.30220.9011.8621 844.520.571.28
Slovenia1.2138.8510.9524 536.800.841.50
Russian Federation1.202130.5457.9110 467.39−0.87−0.50
Indonesia1.18393.0521.393859.81−0.61−0.44
Grenada1.070.024.2610 067.390.511.17
Saudi Arabia1.051595.3974.0521 453.67−1.13−0.42
United Arab Emirates1.03932.2041.4640 322.40−0.19−0.33
South Africa0.99177.8816.746346.73−0.360.09
Sweden0.91214.5314.0452 911.910.561.58
Slovakia0.91202.4123.4118 389.28−0.021.25
Brazil0.88314.6414.468696.90−0.61−0.04
Mexico0.88960.0222.139199.810.261.86
Iran0.82375.7163.133981.87−0.91−0.85
Romania0.7865.188.6811 710.000.261.00
Lithuania0.7743.7214.0718 165.610.340.80
Oman0.63241.7068.8117 047.08−1.26−0.80
Saint Lucia0.600.3725.7610 629.270.640.48
Belarus0.5971.9824.626089.46−0.090.47
Denmark0.5750.995.1358 941.020.680.91
Israel0.5429.414.9841 657.61−0.180.00
Guam0.540.038.5436 407.51−0.14−0.06
Brunei Darussalam0.5260.4291.2529 177.48−0.81−0.16
Philippines0.4917.231.983246.640.20−0.26
Ukraine0.3512.072.453061.800.430.26
Argentina0.3278.2813.0011 566.82−0.78−0.27
Norway0.31580.7955.2574 254.91−0.99−0.53
Estonia0.3118.5311.2221 629.330.280.26
Latvia0.289.626.4916 697.550.320.03
Egypt0.2578.7522.673017.92−0.49−0.75

Note: Like table 10, but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Table 24. Correlates of Country Transition Outlook measures.

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
 OverallOverallOverallGreenGreenGreen
Brown Lock-in Index−0.606***  −0.597***  
 (0.068)  (0.060)  
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)−0.060−0.027−0.0710.116*0.0730.009
 (0.050)(0.060)(0.059)(0.063)(0.069)(0.056)
Coal rents (% of GDP)−0.088***−0.108***−0.105***−0.089***−0.105**−0.096*
 (0.023)(0.034)(0.028)(0.033)(0.049)(0.051)
Oil rents (% of GDP)0.008−0.050***−0.044***0.008−0.038***−0.030***
 (0.006)(0.004)(0.004)(0.006)(0.004)(0.004)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP)−0.011−0.035*−0.031*0.003−0.013−0.011
 (0.010)(0.019)(0.016)(0.012)(0.015)(0.013)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log)0.0010.016−0.0610.136−0.024−0.018
 (0.082)(0.108)(0.098)(0.107)(0.123)(0.103)
Brown Complexity Index −0.140***  0.280*** 
  (0.037)  (0.050) 
Green Complexity Index  0.065  0.405***
   (0.048)  (0.044)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations873873873873873873
R2.356.276.263.344.313.37

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.Dependent variables are country-level transition opportunities from brown to the list stated.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. Note: Like table 3, but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Table 25. Correlates of brown dependence measures.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BLI(4) BCI(5) BCI(6) BCI
GDP per capita (current USD) (log)0.048−0.0130.0590.316***0.179*0.212
 (0.040)(0.050)(0.084)(0.055)(0.099)(0.159)
Coal rents (% of GDP) 0.031  −0.009 
  (0.023)  (0.078) 
Oil rents (% of GDP) 0.089***  −0.025*** 
  (0.006)  (0.005) 
Natural gas rents (% of GDP) 0.035**  −0.017 
  (0.015)  (0.016) 
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log) 0.072  0.420*** 
  (0.099)  (0.158) 
RTA, Environment-related Technologies  1.956  1.364
   (1.204)  (1.836)
RTA, Energy-related Mitigation Technologies  −0.439  −3.384**
   (1.221)  (1.520)
RTA, Carbon Capture and Storage  3.726***  −4.899*
   (0.695)  (2.620)
RTA, Climate Change Adaptation Technologies  0.775  −1.150**
   (0.653)  (0.556)
RTA, Transport-related Mitigation Technologies  −2.569**  2.936
   (1.079)  (2.792)
Year FEsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations961873222961873222
R2.00524.758.203.209.324.173

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question.Dependent variables relate to brown list (narrow). Note: Like table 4, but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Table 26. Predictive power of Green Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (t − 1)0.951***0.923***  
(0.017)(0.035)  
Green Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.003−0.003−0.023**−0.023**
(0.015)(0.016)(0.010)(0.012)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)−0.003−0.0170.029***0.028
(0.009)(0.017)(0.007)(0.018)
Coal rents (% of GDP,$t-1$) 0.025** 0.001
 (0.010) (0.012)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.005 −0.002*
 (0.003) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.002 −0.003**
 (0.003) (0.001)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.028 0.020
 (0.027) (0.028)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.948***0.939***
  (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations749687749687
R2.92.932.917.922

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 5 but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Table 27. Predictive power of overall Transition Outlook.

 (1) BLI(2) BLI(3) BCI(4) BCI
Brown Lock-in Index (t − 1)0.930***0.907***  
(0.019)(0.034)  
Overall Transition Outlook (t − 1)−0.044***−0.032**0.0010.004
(0.014)(0.013)(0.009)(0.012)
GDP per capita (current USD, log, t − 1)−0.006−0.0190.028***0.027
(0.007)(0.016)(0.008)(0.018)
Coal rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.023** 0.003
 (0.010) (0.012)
Oil rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.005 −0.001
 (0.003) (0.001)
Natural gas rents (% of GDP, t − 1) 0.002 −0.003
 (0.003) (0.002)
CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita, log, t − 1) 0.026 0.021
 (0.027) (0.029)
Brown Complexity Index (t − 1)  0.940***0.933***
  (0.015)(0.016)
Year FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations749687749687
R2.921.933.916.922

*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.Linear regression. Cluster-robust standard errors in parenthesis.The label (log) refers to the natural logarithm of 1 + the variable in question. t − 1 refers to the previous period's value. Note: Like table 6, but using an alternative averaging procedure.

Footnotes

  • Variables from OECD Stat are available only for varying subsets of countries in our export dataset.

  • 10 

    The two sampled Kolmogorov–Smirnov test statistic is 0.0499 and the p-value is 0.816.

  • 11 

    Tables 9 and 10, appendix, extend these tables, showing the 50 highest ranking countries.

  • 12 

    Note that this and other regression analyses in this paper are intended to identify correlations. We cannot claim identification of any causal relationships. Instead, our aim is to highlight how the measures we develop relate to one another and, where applicable, whether they are useful in predicting probable future trends.

  • 13 

    An index computed in a similar fashion as Revealed Comparative Advantage, but based on country-level patenting, rather than exports (e.g. Montresor and Quatraro 2017).

  • 14 

    This is consistent with our finding in 3.1 that the proximity of many brown to green products is higher than average, as well as the intuition that countries scoring high on BLI are specialized in a small number of low-complexity brown products located at the periphery of the product space.

  • 15 

    This suggests that countries scoring high in BCI tend to move away from brown and into green activities, while those high in BLI find it easier to transition into undefined areas.

  • 16 

    Both hydrogen and ammonia are labelled based on the type of energy used to produce then, which is green for renewable energy, blue for fossil-based production with carbon-capture and storage, grey for fossil-based production without CCS, and so on.

  • 17 

    Ammonia has pairwise proximity 0.27 to crude oil.

  • 18 

    Methanol has pairwise proximity 0.37 to crude oil, making it crude's closest non-hydrocarbon export.

  • 19 

    Note, however, that absolute export volumes continued to increase.

  • 20 

    These likely include the traditional drivers of agglomeration economies: knowledge spillovers, labour market pooling, and input-output linkages.

  • 21 

    Examples would include hard to decarbonize sectors, such as heavy industry. Steel, for example, is an essential input into many green products, such as wind turbine towers.

  • 22 

    In line with Mealy and Teytelboym (2020), we use the 1992 edition of the Harmonized System to permit us to use the full time series of trade data available from the BACI Database.

Please wait… references are loading.